IRS data shows most Vermonters stay put: What the numbers say about those who moved in
For three years in a row, more people have moved into Vermont than out, and many of them were well-off, according to data from the IRS.
The nonprofit Public Assets Institute in Montpelier analyzed recently released IRS data from tax filings in 2022 to determine that two of the years of growth in Vermont's population occurred during the COVID pandemic in 2021 and 2022. More than half of the people arriving in Vermont in 2022 were so-called millennials − the generation born between 1981 and 1996 − and a quarter of those who moved here had incomes of $100,000 or more annually.
The IRS has collected data on movement of the population between states for more than 35 years, based on tax filings, and in 2012 the agency also started tracking migration by age and income of the primary filer. Public Assets points out that because of how the data are collected, they can see only the age of the person filing the return and the total number of exemptions, which they use as a proxy for the number of people in the household.
The IRS data does not include specific information on the makeup of households, however, such as the number and ages of children. Neither does the data distinguish how much of the total income was received before or after the taxpayer arrived in Vermont.
Public Assets drew the following conclusions from the IRS data:
Half of all filers who moved into Vermont in 2022 were 26 to 44 years old, an age range that closely matches the millennial generation. It appears some in that age group arrived with children, but it's impossible to know how many. The state saw a decrease in only one age bracket: filers under 26. Vermont saw a drop of about 500 people in their early 20s, but in all other age brackets, from young professionals to seniors, Vermont saw population growth from migration, wtih millennials accounting for the largest share of overall growth.
The IRS data on income undercut an often repeated claim that the wealthy are fleeing Vermont, according to Public Assets. From 2012 to 2022, Vermont had a net gain in filers with incomes of $200,000 or more in all but one year. In 2022, for every three filers in that income bracket who left the state, five moved in. Based on the most recent data, Vermont saw net gains among filers with incomes of $50,000 or more and net losses among filers earning less than $50,000. Just more than half of the filers who moved out of the state earned less than $50,000.
Nearly half of all people who moved out of Vermont in 2022 stayed in the northeastern United States, with more than a third relocating across the border to a neighboring state. This was also true for people moving into Vermont − more than a third moved from New York, New Hampshire and Massachusetts. Overall, only about 3% of Vermonters moved out in 2022, which has been the pattern for 30 years. We like it here.
Contact Dan D'Ambrosio at 660-1841 or ddambrosio@freepressmedia.com. Follow him on Twitter @DanDambrosioVT.
This article originally appeared on Burlington Free Press: IRS data shows wealthy millennials moved to Vermont during COVID
Hashtags

Try Our AI Features
Explore what Daily8 AI can do for you:
Comments
No comments yet...
Related Articles

Miami Herald
16 minutes ago
- Miami Herald
Costco sees one huge area for sales growth, happier members
Costco has never been a leader in much other than offering members low prices. The company only innovates when it has to. During the Covid pandemic, for example, it took charge of its own shipping containers. That was a move made out of need, but it proved the company can be agile when possible. Related: Bankrupt beauty brand to return after $1 billion collapse It has also done really well with Costco Logistics, a company it created because it did not like any of the other options it had for making larger deliveries. "It's about 20% to 25% of our total deliveries for Costco Logistics, but it is about 80% to 85% of our big and bulky," CEO Ron Vachris said during Costco's third-quarter earnings call. Don't miss the move: Subscribe to TheStreet's free daily newsletter The warehouse club has let its managers make decisions for use to use that resource. "We make our buyers make decisions of what to put through that network and what not to put through it. And so, they look for the best cost delivery source. And so, we know that big and bulky patio furniture, television, safe, those kind of things, all but the super specialty stuff we run through Costco Logistics. So, a big chunk of that business is going through the network of big and bulky," he added. Delivery, however, may not be the biggest opportunity Costco (COST) has. Image source: Bloomberg/Getty Images For years, Costco had a website, but did not even sell anything online. That has changed and the chain not only sells some of what it offers in its warehouses, but also deals from third-party sellers. The warehouse club also has an app, and CFO Gary Millerchip thinks that the company has barely scratched the surface of the potential there. He was asked about it during the call. "And are there any members that haven't used your digital yet in some way, shape or form, or is it still only half the people that really use it?" asked Greg Melich. Millerchip was enthusiastic in his response. "Yeah. It's over half has downloaded the app for sure, but there's still plenty of opportunity for growth in our mind. We still see it as an area where we'd expect to outpace our overall growth," he added. More on travel: US government warns of dating app use in popular cruise portsCarnival Cruise Line rep sounds alarm on growing YouTube problemWhat the CDC's Dengue Fever warning means for Caribbean travel It's not just about getting members to use the app, but also making it better. "And as we continue to improve the member experience with enhancements every quarter, Greg around, whether it's the inventory available on the app or improving the search functionality, improving the way in which we communicate with members, as I talked about earlier on the call, we believe all of those things are going to drive more digital engagement," he added. Millerchip believes that the Costco app may also have in-store uses as well. "We think tied to even some of the comments that Ron was making about speed of checkout, where members use their digital wallet and have their payment card integrated within the wallet, it significantly increases the speed of checkout through the check lane in the warehouse as well," he said. The CFO also made it clear that the app might be useful in ways he's not even considered yet. "So, we still think there's plenty of opportunity to keep driving higher penetration of digital engagement with our members and we think it's got a runway to continue to grow in the future," he added. Related: TSA shares travel warning for Costco members Vachris made more comments on digital and the app later in the call. "We found that digital really enhances the speed of checkout. And so, we are really working hard on the digital membership card usage as well. We've also engaged in some "Scan & Go done by Costco" kind of tests that we're doing out there that have been extremely successful of moving people through the lines and expediting the transactions," he said. "We've seen some very, very early results have been very positive and great adoption from our members seeing that as well." The Arena Media Brands, LLC THESTREET is a registered trademark of TheStreet, Inc.
Yahoo
an hour ago
- Yahoo
Anti-Virus Coating Market to Exceed USD 12 Billion by 2034
Anti-Virus Coating Market Outlook 2025-2034 Luton, Bedfordshire, United Kingdom,, June 09, 2025 (GLOBE NEWSWIRE) -- The global anti-virus coating market is undergoing a dynamic transformation, spurred by heightened public awareness around hygiene and infection control, particularly following the COVID-19 pandemic. Valued at approximately USD 4.5 billion in 2024, the market is anticipated to expand at a robust CAGR of 12%, reaching an estimated USD 12 billion by 2034. This growth is being fueled by demand from various sectors such as healthcare, transportation, electronics, and construction, all seeking to implement protective surface technologies that limit the spread of viruses and bacteria. The emergence of nanotechnology and eco-friendly coating formulations is expected to further propel the market, setting a new standard for health-focused innovation. Download PDF Brochure: Market Segmentation: A Diverse and Evolving Landscape By Type Anti-virus coatings are broadly categorized into antimicrobial, antiviral, biocidal, and self-cleaning coatings. Antimicrobial coatings lead the market, comprising around 45% of the global share, and are extensively used in healthcare and public facilities. These coatings are effective in reducing microbial growth on surfaces, ensuring sustained sanitation. Antiviral coatings, which deactivate viruses upon contact, have gained rapid traction, especially post-pandemic, now accounting for approximately 20% of the market. These are frequently deployed in high-traffic public areas and transport systems. Biocidal coatings, with their broader microbial resistance, contribute around 15% of the market share and are favored in industrial settings. Meanwhile, self-cleaning coatings—though holding a smaller share of around 10%—are growing steadily in residential and commercial sectors due to their maintenance-free appeal. By Material The market divides into organic and inorganic coatings. Organic coatings, constituting 60% of the market, are popular for their affordability and ease of application. However, they face increasing competition from inorganic coatings, which make up the remaining 40%. Inorganic variants are noted for their superior durability and are often chosen for demanding environments such as aerospace and automotive applications. By Application In terms of application, healthcare remains the largest segment, absorbing 35% of the market, where coatings are essential for infection control in hospitals and clinics. Public facilities follow, with around 25% market share, as schools, government buildings, and transportation hubs prioritize hygiene. The residential sector, accounting for 15%, is growing thanks to consumer demand for cleaner living spaces. Transportation, including buses, trains, and airplanes, also holds a 15% share as part of global efforts to ensure safe travel. The hospitality sector, encompassing hotels and restaurants, contributes around 10%, focusing on cleanliness to reassure customers and maintain service quality. By End-User Industry The automotive industry leads with a 30% share as manufacturers incorporate antiviral coatings into interiors to protect passengers. The electronics sector follows at 20%, where smart devices benefit from hygienic, touch-safe surfaces. Food and beverage processing utilizes coatings for sanitation compliance, contributing around 15%. The construction sector, representing 25%, is increasingly adopting coatings for both aesthetic and protective reasons. Meanwhile, the aerospace industry, although smaller at 10%, sees high demand due to rigorous safety protocols. Browse full Report - Market Segmentation By Type: - Antimicrobial Coatings Antiviral Coatings Biocidal Coatings Self-Cleaning Coatings By Material: - Organic Coatings Inorganic Coatings By Application: - Healthcare Public Facilities Residential Transportation Hospitality By End-user Industry: - Automotive Aerospace Electronics Food & Beverage Building & Construction By Region: - North America Latin America Europe Asia-Pacific Middle East & Africa Regional Analysis: Asia-Pacific Takes the Lead The Asia-Pacific region dominates the anti-virus coating market with about 40% of the global revenue. This growth is driven by booming consumer electronics, a large population base, and rising health consciousness across countries like China, India, and Japan. Supportive regulatory frameworks and strong manufacturing bases make this region the global hub for coating innovation and deployment. North America follows, accounting for 30% of the market. With well-established healthcare infrastructure, high hygiene awareness, and significant investment in R&D, this region continues to push the boundaries of coating technologies. Government incentives and consumer demand for safer environments post-pandemic further support market expansion. Europe, contributing 25%, benefits from stringent hygiene standards mandated by governing bodies such as the EU. Sectors like food processing, public transport, and healthcare heavily rely on advanced coatings to comply with these regulations. The region's technological maturity enhances innovation and accelerates product adoption. Emerging regions such as Latin America and the Middle East & Africa present strong growth potential despite current limitations. Latin America is expected to grow at a CAGR of 9% due to increasing urbanization and healthcare investment. The Middle East and Africa, although starting from a smaller base, are experiencing rising awareness around sanitation and could see parallel growth if political and regulatory barriers are addressed. Market Drivers: Innovation, Regulation, and Awareness Several key factors are propelling the market forward. Chief among them is the global shift in hygiene awareness following the COVID-19 pandemic. Institutions, businesses, and individuals are actively seeking reliable and long-lasting surface protection solutions. This has driven demand across public transportation, offices, homes, and educational institutions. Technological innovation is another major driver. Nanotechnology enables coatings with extended life, higher effectiveness, and self-sanitizing properties. These innovations address the demand for sustainable, non-toxic, and highly efficient coatings, boosting industry credibility and consumer trust. Government regulations are also shaping the market. Mandatory hygiene protocols, particularly in healthcare and public infrastructure, have compelled industries to invest in antiviral and antimicrobial solutions. Incentives and subsidies for infection-control products have made it easier for manufacturers to innovate and for end-users to adopt these technologies. Market Challenges: Regulatory, Economic, and Supply Chain Barriers Despite its strong outlook, the anti-virus coating market faces notable challenges. Volatile raw material prices, driven by supply chain disruptions and geopolitical tensions, can impact production costs and profitability. The reliance on specific chemical inputs makes the industry sensitive to global trade dynamics. Stringent regulatory environments can be both a driver and a constraint. While promoting higher safety standards, compliance requirements often increase operational costs, especially for small and mid-sized enterprises. Navigating international standards can also complicate market entry for newer players. Pricing pressure in a competitive market poses additional hurdles. As consumers look for affordable solutions, manufacturers must balance cost with product quality. In some cases, lower-cost competitors may compromise efficacy, undermining overall industry reputation. Sourcing sustainable raw materials remains a challenge, especially as green certifications become a requirement in more countries. This can slow down R&D cycles and inflate production costs, affecting speed to market. Emerging Trends and Opportunities The anti-virus coating market presents ample opportunities for growth, especially in emerging economies where health infrastructure is evolving. Manufacturers can tailor products to regional needs, leveraging urbanization and increased public health spending. One of the most promising trends is the development of multifunctional coatings—products that offer both antiviral and antimicrobial properties, as well as features like self-cleaning and aesthetic enhancement. These innovations appeal to a broad range of industries and reduce the need for multiple surface treatments. Digital integration is also on the horizon. Smart coatings embedded with IoT sensors can report contamination levels or indicate when reapplication is needed. This has promising applications in hospitals and food processing where hygiene monitoring is critical. Subscription models for ongoing coating application and maintenance services are another emerging opportunity, especially in commercial real estate, hotels, and educational institutions. This allows businesses to ensure hygiene standards are consistently met without managing logistics in-house. Buy Now: Key Competitors AkzoNobel PPG Industries Sherwin-Williams BASF Dow Inc. 3M Company Nippon Paint Holdings DuPont Hempel A/S Jotun Group RPM International Tnemec Company, Inc. Laticrete International, Inc. Rust-Oleum Corporation Valspar Corporation Recent Developments: Competitive Moves Shaping the Market AkzoNobel launched a new line of anti-virus coatings in November 2023, targeting healthcare and public sectors with enhanced durability and sustainability. The innovation reflects a strategic pivot to address growing demands in high-contact environments. 3M Company, in October 2023, acquired a start-up specializing in antiviral coating technology. This acquisition bolsters 3M's presence in healthcare and PPE markets by incorporating cutting-edge antiviral formulations. In August 2023, PPG Industries gained regulatory approval for a new coating designed for commercial indoor surfaces, a move that elevates its credibility and expands its customer base in regulated environments. BASF, in June 2023, introduced nanotechnology-based coatings with superior resistance and performance, targeting high-traffic areas such as hospitals, transit systems, and schools. Nippon Paint Holdings announced its expansion into Southeast Asia in March 2023, capitalizing on growing regional demand. This strategic move enhances its global footprint and positions it competitively in emerging markets. This report is also available in the following languages : Japanese (抗ウイルスコーティング市場), Korean (항바이러스 코팅 시장), Chinese (防病毒涂料市场), French (Marché des revêtements antivirus), German (Markt für Antivirenbeschichtungen), and Italian (Mercato dei rivestimenti antivirus), etc. Request Sample Pages: More Research Finding – Lithium Battery Coating Market The global lithium battery coating market is poised to reach an estimated value of $1.2 billion in 2024, driven by the expanding demand for electric vehicles (EVs) and renewable energy storage solutions. As manufacturers increasingly prioritize battery efficiency and longevity, the market is expected to grow at a Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of approximately 10.5% from 2025 to 2034, potentially reaching $3.3 billion by the end of the forecast period. Helmet Anti-Fog Coatings Market The global helmet anti-fog coatings market is valued at approximately $150 million in 2024, with a projected value of around $320 million by 2034. This growth reflects a substantial Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of 8.1% over the forecast period (2025–2034). Aero Engine Coating Market The global aero engines coating market size is expected to grow at 5.7% CAGR from 2022 to 2029. It is expected to reach above USD 2.93 billion by 2029 from USD 1.78 billion in 2020. Medical Nano Coatings Market The global medical nano coatings market is valued at approximately $1.8 billion in 2024, with a projected market value of $4.5 billion by 2034. This growth represents a robust compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of around 9.4% during the forecast period from 2025 to 2034. Dual Therapy Stent Market The dual therapy stent market is valued at approximately $1.5 billion, with projections indicating a market value of $2.9 billion by 2034. This growth reflects a Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of around 7.1% from 2025 to 2034. Methyl Etherified Amino Resin Market The global Methyl Etherified Amino Resin market is valued at approximately $1.2 billion, reflecting strong demand across various industries, including automotive, construction, and consumer goods. The market is projected to reach around $2.1 billion by 2034, showcasing significant growth driven by increasing applications in coatings and adhesive formulations. PE Micronized Wax Market The global micronized wax market, valued at approximately $1.2 billion in 2024, is poised for significant expansion, with projections indicating it could reach around $2.3 billion by 2034. This translates to a robust Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of 7.1% between 2025 and 2034. Organic Peroxide Initiator Market The global organic peroxide initiator market was valued at approximately $3.5 billion in 2024, driven by increasing demand in the polymer and rubber sectors. The market is poised for robust growth, with a projected value of around $5.6 billion by 2034. This growth corresponds to a Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of approximately 4.8% over the forecast period from 2025 to 2034. General Industry Coatings Market The global general industry coatings market is valued at approximately $30 billion in 2024, reflecting steady demand across various sectors. By 2034, the market is projected to reach around $42 billion, indicating robust growth driven by increasing industrial activities and infrastructure development. The estimated Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) for the forecast period from 2025 to 2034 is 4.5%, fueled by advancements in coating technologies and a rising emphasis on sustainability. MXene Material Market The global MXene market is valued at approximately $390 million, with projections estimating its growth to around $1.2 billion by 2034. This growth corresponds to a robust Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of about 12.2% during the forecast period from 2025 to 2034. Biomass Furan Dicarboxylic Acid FDCA Market The global market for biomass-derived furan dicarboxylic acid (FDCA) is valued at approximately $240 million. The market is poised for substantial growth, with a projected value of $1.2 billion by 2034. This growth trajectory translates to a compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of around 17.5% during the forecast period from 2025 to 2034. Bio-based Epoxy Resins Market The global bio-based epoxy resins market is valued at approximately $1.8 billion in 2024, driven by the increasing demand for sustainable materials across various industries, including automotive, construction, and electronics. The market is projected to reach around $3.5 billion by 2034, reflecting a significant growth trajectory. With a Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of about 6.8% from 2025 to 2034. Organoclay Powder Market The global organoclay powder market is valued at approximately $1.6 billion in 2024, influenced by rising demand in industries such as oilfield, coatings, plastics, and personal care. Anticipating robust growth, the market is projected to reach around $2.5 billion by 2034, reflecting the escalating use of organoclays in applications requiring enhanced performance characteristics. High Refractive Index Monomer Market The global high refractive index monomer market is anticipated to reach approximately $2.1 billion in 2024, driven by increasing demand in optical applications, including eyewear lenses, automotive components, and electronic displays. The market is expected to exhibit robust growth with a projected value of around $3.5 billion by 2034, reflecting a compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of 5.2% during the forecast period from 2025 to 2034. Superfine Precipitated Barium Sulphate Market The superfine precipitated barium sulfate market is estimated to reach a value of approximately $1.2 billion in 2024, with projections indicating a growth trajectory to around $2.0 billion by 2034. This represents a Compound Annual Growth Rate (CAGR) of 5.5% for the period between 2025 and 2034. CONTACT: Irfan Tamboli (Head of Sales) Phone: + 1704 266 3234 Email: sales@ in retrieving data Sign in to access your portfolio Error in retrieving data Error in retrieving data Error in retrieving data Error in retrieving data


Forbes
an hour ago
- Forbes
In Facebook Case, the Cost-Sharing Regulations Pass Their First Test
Although Tax Court Judge Cary Douglas Pugh rejected the IRS's position on almost every key methodological detail in Facebook Inc. v. Commissioner, 164 T.C. No. 9 (2025), her opinion vindicated the general legitimacy of the method and the regulatory scheme that introduced it. Like most other major section 482 cases, especially those involving contributions to cost-sharing agreements (CSAs), Facebook was largely a clash between the parties' economists. Both sides leaned heavily on valuation reports by expert witnesses to support their vastly differing valuations of Facebook's platform contributions to a 2010 CSA with its Irish subsidiary, which included core technologies and a preexisting user base. In this battle of economists, the IRS clearly lost. Pugh's opinion repeatedly expressed frustration with both parties' valuation experts for acting more like advocates than experts. However, she found the IRS's expert witness to be particularly unreliable. The two most critical inputs when applying the income method under the 2009 temporary cost-sharing regulations (T.D. 9441) are financial projections and discount rates, and Pugh rejected the IRS lead witness's testimony on both. Pugh was even more critical of the IRS's reliance on an unusual and aggressive variation of the income method. The cumulative monetary effect of these setbacks for the IRS will be dramatic. The final platform contribution transaction (PCT) value won't be official until Rule 155 computations are complete, but Pugh estimated that applying the income method with reliable inputs would yield a roughly $7.8 billion PCT value — far closer to Facebook's $6.3 billion valuation than to the $19.9 billion value derived from the IRS's method. Based on this estimate, less than 11 percent of the IRS's total PCT value adjustment would stand. The tax revenue gain will still exceed the IRS's litigation costs, but in purely monetary terms, Facebook hardly looks like a major IRS victory. However, a win for Facebook on the facts isn't necessarily a loss for the IRS. The $12.2 billion difference between the IRS's PCT valuation and the value tentatively cited by Pugh was entirely attributable to inputs and other methodological details. These were ultimately questions of fact, and their relevance is limited to the facts of this case. On questions of statutory and regulatory interpretation, which have ramifications that extend far beyond this case, Facebook was a resounding IRS win. Billions of dollars are at stake in Facebook, and the case pairs one of the world's best-known and most polarizing companies with one of U.S. tax law's most widely exploited and frequently criticized profit-shifting tools. But Facebook is, above all, the first judicial test of the cost-sharing regulatory regime created by the 2009 temporary regulations, which was the product of a painstaking effort to fix the loopholes (real or perceived) responsible for the IRS's losses in Veritas Software Corp. v. Commissioner, 133 T.C. 297 (2009), nonacq., AOD 2010-05, and Inc. v. Commissioner, 148 T.C. No. 8 (2017), aff'd, 934 F.3d 976 (9th Cir. 2019). In Veritas and again in Amazon, which was later affirmed by the Ninth Circuit, the Tax Court held that the buy-in requirement for 'preexisting intangible' contributions in the 1995 regulations (T.D. 8632) excluded residual business assets like goodwill and intangibles developed over the life of the CSA. This was a consequence of restrictions that, according to the Tax Court and Ninth Circuit, followed from reg. section 1.482-4(b)'s definition of intangible and the modifier 'preexisting.' Because the buy-in payments derived from the IRS's discounted cash flow (DCF) valuations included the value of residual business assets and later developed intangibles, courts held that the 1995 regulations prohibited their use. To stop the uncompensated transfers of valuable assets allowed by this interpretation, the 2009 temporary regulations and the substantially identical 2011 final regulations (T.D. 9568) replaced the term 'preexisting intangible' with 'platform contribution.' This decoupled CSA participants' PCT payment obligations from any definitional limitations inherited from reg. section 1.482-4(b). It also clarified that the PCT value must include the value of intangibles developed under the CSA to the extent that their development benefited from access to the platform contribution. Arguably more important than these terminology changes was the introduction of specified PCT valuation methods that mechanically prevent artificial exclusions. The 1995 cost-sharing regulations cross-referenced reg. section 1.482-4 for pricing methods, and DCF valuations are permitted by reg. section 1.482-4 only as 'unspecified methods.' Courts thus consistently turned to the comparable uncontrolled transaction method, which allows for the kinds of exclusions that DCF valuations do not. It also indulged the historical judicial preference for transactional methods. The specified PCT valuation method at issue in Facebook is the income method, and it is a close cousin of the DCF valuations rejected in Veritas and Amazon. Similar to a DCF valuation, it derives the PCT value by discounting projected income to present value, and it provides no plausible basis for carving out excluded items. The IRS's ability to defend its selection of the income method in Facebook was thus the first test of the new regulatory scheme's ability to prevent another Veritas or Amazon. To some, it seemed hard to conceive of any plausible basis for reading the old exclusions and methodological preferences into the new law. It would be counterintuitive, to say the least, if the interpretations of the 1995 regulations that compelled Treasury and the IRS to draft a more elaborate version of reg. section 1.482-7 from scratch somehow remained viable under the new regulatory scheme. Construing the 2009 cost-sharing regulations to exclude residual business asset value and prioritize transactional methods would be like reading Prohibition into the 21st Amendment. It would turn the regulatory scheme on its head. But this view was never unanimous. Undaunted tax advisers proposed ways to resurrect the old loopholes, and skeptics criticized the whole effort for legitimizing an irredeemably flawed profit-shifting technique. Until the Tax Court released its Facebook opinion, the only real signal of how courts would interpret the new regulations was in a footnote to the Ninth Circuit's Amazon opinion: "If this case were governed by the 2009 regulations or by the 2017 statutory amendment, there is no doubt the Commissioner's position would be correct." What's correct may not have been in doubt. What would actually happen when a taxpayer tested this prediction certainly was. Facebook's briefs attest to what must have been a determined and all-encompassing search for a winning legal theory, and some of Pugh's comments at trial arguably suggested skepticism toward the income method. The legal questions presented in Facebook won't be definitively resolved until at least one or, more likely, multiple appeals courts confirm the answers. But in Facebook, the income method and the regulatory scheme that introduced it passed their first major test. What was clearly correct to the Ninth Circuit panel that decided Amazon was clear to Pugh as well. Any inferences to the contrary drawn from Pugh's questions at trial and dissent in 3M Co. v. Commissioner, 160 T.C. No. 3 (2023), were apparently misguided. Pugh found that the IRS derived its PCT value from a severely flawed application of the income method, and these findings had a drastic effect on the PCT value. But she unequivocally affirmed the general validity of the income method, and by extension the regulatory scheme, despite Facebook's determined effort to discredit it. As the opinion concludes: 'Applying the statute and regulations, we conclude that using the income method to determine the requisite PCT Payment value and resulting payments for 2010 produces an arm's-length result if the correct inputs are used. . . . The regulations themselves are not invalid merely because they impose a limit on the expected return on [intangible development costs] at a discount rate reflecting market-correlated risks.' The basic premise underlying the income method is that, for CSAs in which only one party makes any nonroutine platform contribution, the PCT value should equal the difference between the net present value (NPV) of entering the CSA and the NPV of entering the best realistic alternative transaction. The PCT value is thus the difference between the NPV of the PCT payer's reasonably anticipated operating income under the cost-sharing alternative and the NPV of its operating income under the hypothetical best realistic alternative. In general, although not in Facebook, the PCT payer's best realistic alternative is to license the right to exploit the cost-shared intangibles from an independent developer. The NPV of the best realistic alternative is thus the present value of the PCT payer's expected returns as a hypothetical licensee, as determined using either the comparable profits method or the CUT method. In effect, the income method forces the PCT payer to hand the expected NPV excess associated with CSA participation back to the participant responsible for the nonroutine platform contribution. This leaves the PCT payer with an expected return on the cash it invests in the CSA equal to the cost-sharing alternative discount rate, which represents the return that a market investor could expect to earn on an investment with the same risk profile as the CSA activity. If the PCT payer makes nonroutine contributions specific to its own territory, the income method requires that the payer's best realistic alternative be adjusted to reflect a return on its contributions. This approach follows from the general 'investor model,' which provides that all PCT valuation methods should offer CSA participants a return on their aggregate net investment commensurate with the CSA activity's risk profile. A corollary of this principle is that all cash contributions included in 'aggregate net investment' should have a uniform expected rate of return, regardless of whether they take the form of a PCT payment or a cost contribution. As reg. section 1.482-7(g)(2)(ii) explains: 'The relative reliability of an application of a method also depends on the degree of consistency of the analysis with the assumption that, as of the date of the PCT, each controlled participant's aggregate net investment in the CSA Activity (including platform contributions, operating contributions . . . and cost contributions) is reasonably anticipated to earn a rate of return (which might be reflected in a discount rate used in applying a method) appropriate to the riskiness of the controlled participant's CSA Activity over the entire period of such CSA Activity.' The method's logic is sound. The income method is appropriate only when the PCT payer makes no nonroutine platform contributions, so the payer's principal contribution to the CSA will be the cash it invests through the PCT payment and cost contributions. The arm's-length return for a cash contribution is the expected return available to market investors for bearing the risk associated with the CSA activity, and this is what the CSA discount rate represents. Unless the PCT payer makes nonroutine contributions of its own, any excess in its expected returns over the CSA discount rate must be attributable to the PCT payee's platform contribution. One could reasonably suggest that the discount rate for developing sophisticated and potentially extraordinarily valuable technologies, which Pugh found to be 17.7 percent in Facebook, overcompensates PCT payers that don't functionally contribute to cost-shared intangible development. But it prevents the far more egregious results made possible under the 1995 regulations by the residual business assets exclusion, the use of decay curves and finite useful lives, and the general judicial aversion to income-based valuation methods. The income method generates an aggregate PCT value that reflects the full NPV difference between alternatives, and it provides no basis for carving out value attributable to excluded assets. If the income method didn't establish a meaningful limit on profit shifting, a taxpayer like Facebook wouldn't make such a determined effort to invalidate it. Facebook upheld the general validity of a method that aggregates the value of all platform contributions, and in doing so, it implicitly rejected the notion that a residual business asset exclusion survives hidden somewhere in the 2009 and 2011 regulations. Pugh expressly rejected that notion as well, and in short order: 'Petitioner also spends a couple of pages in its opening brief on an argument that Facebook Ireland should not be required to compensate Facebook US for residual business assets. It is true that the definition of intangible property in the second sentence of section 482 in 2010 was limited to the intangible property listed under section 936(h)(3)(B). But the first sentence of section 482 has no such limits; the statute does not constrain the contributions to a CSA that might be compensable through a PCT Payment.' Facebook's more intricate methodological objections, including its 'zero NPV' critique, fared no better. During briefing, Facebook's zero NPV argument seized on the arithmetic relationship between the PCT value and the NPVs of the two alternatives. Because the PCT value is equal to the NPV of the cost-sharing alternative minus the NPV of the licensing alternative, the post-PCT NPV difference between the two alternatives is, by definition, zero. In other words, the income method requires that the PCT payer transfer all of the incremental value associated with entering the CSA back to the PCT payee. According to Facebook, the arm's-length standard entitles cost-sharing participants to retain some of the NPV excess associated with CSA participation. However, as Pugh rightly observed in her opinion, claiming that a PCT payer's cost contributions have an expected rate of return in excess of the discount rate would discredit every PCT method based on the investor model. This claim, the opinion explains, implies that PCT payers should receive a preferential rate of return in excess of what a market investor would receive on the same investment: 'Petitioner's objection that a generic investor would seek a return that is greater than its cost of capital proves too much. It necessarily assumes that this investment should be more attractive than another similar investment. The arm's-length standard does not require a preferred return (a positive NPV); it requires a return comparable to returns on other similar investments. Moreover, petitioner does not explain why in a controlled transaction, such as this, a positive NPV for Facebook Ireland would not result in a negative NPV for Facebook US.' Another way in which the income method allegedly shortchanges PCT payers is by denying them a return for the entrepreneurial risks and functions associated with exploiting the cost-shared intangibles in their territory. Echoing reg. section 1.482-7(g)(4)(vi)(E), Pugh explained that any such contributions can be accounted for by properly valuing the licensing alternative: 'To the extent petitioner's objection is that Facebook Ireland receives no return for its entrepreneurial contributions, that is addressed by proper comparables for the licensing alternative. . . . It is incorrect therefore to conclude that the income method denies an economic profit for any entrepreneurial efforts of the PCT Payor. Petitioner's objections are addressed through selection of the proper inputs into the income method.' Consistently applying this reasoning also led Pugh to reject the way in which the IRS applied the income method in Facebook. The regulations generally assume that the PCT payer's best realistic alternative transaction will be to license the cost-shared intangibles from the developer. This assumption shifts all development risk to the developer, but it leaves the risks associated with exploiting the cost-shared intangibles with the PCT payer. As the final cost-sharing regulations provide (in reg. section 1.482-7(g)(4)(i)): 'In general, the best realistic alternative of the PCT Payor to entering into the CSA would be to license intangibles to be developed by an uncontrolled licensor that undertakes the commitment to bear the entire risk of intangible development that would otherwise have been shared under the CSA. [Emphasis added.] But the IRS valuation expert instead used a 'services alternative' as the best realistic alternative, which treated Facebook Ireland as though it were a low-risk marketing services provider. Under the services alternative, Facebook Ireland received a cost-plus markup of 8 percent, which was nominally based on a set of marketing services companies that bore none of the exploitation risk typically associated with the licensing alternative. Although the 8 percent markup was within the interquartile range (6.8 to 14.2 percent) for the comparables set, it was well below the median value (13.9 percent). Whether it's necessary or appropriate to reward PCT payers with an expected return consistent with the returns of real risk-bearing licensees is open for debate. But the reason that Facebook's theoretical criticism of the income method failed is also the reason that, at least under the regulations, the IRS's services alternative approach was inappropriate. Calculating the PCT value by reference to alternatives with drastically different risk profiles also raises major practical problems, including those associated with a wide discount rate differential that cannot be attributed to a specific risk. Unlike a services alternative, the licensing alternative can differ from the cost-sharing alternative in narrow and predefined ways that relate only to development risk. It's unclear why the IRS opted to use a novel and more aggressive variation of the income method when the method's overall validity was at stake. But it was logically consistent for Pugh to uphold the income method in general while rejecting the method's application in Facebook, and the trade-off for the IRS was a favorable one. By confirming the income method's general validity, Facebook tentatively vindicates the foundations of the current cost-sharing regulations. Pugh rejected Facebook's attempts to create a new residual business asset exclusion and invalidate the investor model, both of which were critical for the regulatory scheme to function. But Pugh's endorsement of the income method's arm's-length bona fides in Facebook followed from her interpretation of the arm's-length standard in general, which could have implications that extend far beyond cost sharing. For Facebook, the income method's zero-NPV effect is invalidating because it creates a conflict between reg. section 1.482-7(g)(4) and the arm's-length standard. This assumes that Treasury and the IRS had an obligation to conform reg. section 1.482-7(g)(4) to the arm's-length standard. It also assumes that the arm's-length standard is a transactional and comparables-based concept, regardless of what the regulations say on the matter. As noted in Facebook, this interpretation implies that any transactional evidence at all takes priority over the methodological reliability standards specified by regulation: 'Where there are no uncontrolled comparables, petitioner maintains, the arm's-length standard requires a 'method that is expected to most closely approximate the way in which unrelated parties price transactions.' Petitioner submits that this approximation can be accomplished through sources such as peer-reviewed academic literature and broad industry standards.' The two assumptions underlying Facebook's argument are related, and the distinction between the two is often blurred. But they are distinct. Whether Treasury and the IRS have a statutory obligation to adhere to something that falls within the ambit of the arm's-length standard is one question, and whether they have to interpret the arm's-length standard in a narrow and archaic way is another. On the first question, Pugh emphasized that the applicable statutory standard established by the first sentence of section 482 is a clear reflection of income. Her opinion observes that 'neither sentence of section 482 expressly adopts the arm's-length standard,' which 'originated in the regulations promulgated under the Revenue Act of 1934.' Only the sentence added by the Tax Reform Act of 1986 directly addresses controlled intangible transfers, Pugh said, and it does not support Facebook's contention: 'The only statutory touchstone relating to intangibles in section 482 is the 'commensurate with the income' requirement. That addition seems to move the statute away from, not toward, an 'arm's length' standard, at least as petitioner defines it; it requires compensation commensurate with the income earned in the transaction. [Emphasis added.] The Facebook opinion doesn't directly say whether Treasury and the IRS could issue regulations that openly repudiate the arm's-length standard. But if the statute doesn't bind Treasury and the IRS to the arm's-length standard, then any obligation to apply it would be a self-imposed regulatory restraint on their broader statutory authority. It would follow that Treasury and the IRS have the right to specify the terms of that self-imposed restraint. However, in Facebook and other best method cases, the authority to openly abandon the arm's-length standard is less important than the discretion to interpret it. On the second question, Pugh was unequivocal. Drawing heavily on the Ninth Circuit majority's reasoning in Altera Corp. v. Commissioner, 926 F.3d 1061 (9th Cir. 2019), rev'g 145 T.C. 91 (2015), Pugh rejected the antiquated interpretation of the arm's-length standard favored by Facebook and other taxpayers: 'In Altera, the Ninth Circuit expressly held that in the light of concerns over third-party comparables, a focus on internal allocations that follow economic activity is an appropriate method to reach an arm's-length result.' Pugh's unqualified reliance on Altera in Facebook is significant in multiple respects. Although Altera is binding circuit precedent in Facebook, Pugh's opinion reflects a broader acceptance of the Ninth Circuit's reasoning. It also confirms that, at least in the Tax Court's view, the Ninth Circuit's holding was unaffected by Loper Bright Enterprises Inc. v. Raimondo, 603 U.S. 369 (2024). Therefore, all taxpayer validity challenges targeting the cost-sharing regulations' treatment of stock-based compensation, including in Abbott Laboratories v. Commissioner, No. 20227-23, and McKesson Corp. v. United States, No. 3:25-cv-01102, should fail. Perhaps even more significant, Pugh's reliance on Altera in a best method case thwarts a ubiquitous and foundational element of taxpayers' arguments in methodological disputes. As the Facebook opinion explains: 'Petitioner attempts to convert the arm's-length standard, as defined in Treas. Reg. section 1.482-1, into an independent rule. But nothing in the text of section 482 bars Treasury from prescribing what arm's length means when no comparable transactions can be identified. Section 482 does not contain the words 'arm's length'; rather, its focus is on clear reflection of income and preventing tax evasion in controlled transactions.' In other words, neither section 482 nor reg. section 1.482-1's general articulation of the arm's-length standard provides any basis for invalidating the method-specific provisions that apply them. This is critical because manufacturing such conflicts has become the basis for taxpayer attacks on all income-based methods, including the CPM in Medtronic Inc. v. Commissioner, T.C. Memo. 2022-84. If legitimized by courts, those conflicts would twist the section 482 regulations into an ineffectual knot. The significance of upholding one of the centerpieces of the 2009 cost-sharing regulations, and by extension the regulatory scheme itself, in Facebook can't be understated. But the Tax Court's broader acceptance of Altera, and the corresponding rejection of an inappropriately narrow interpretation of the arm's-length standard, is arguably even more important. For the IRS, these victories on the law far outweigh its loss on the facts in Facebook.