logo
Mount Everest's Record-Setting Sherpa Sees a Future of Snowless Mountains and Fewer Guides

Mount Everest's Record-Setting Sherpa Sees a Future of Snowless Mountains and Fewer Guides

New York Times28-05-2025
Kami Rita Sherpa, a renowned Nepali mountain guide, completed his 31st climb of Mount Everest on Tuesday, breaking his own record for the most successful trips to the mountain's peak.
For more than 30 years, Mr. Rita, 55, has helped climbers from all over the world reach the top of the mountain. The New York Times spoke to him about his long career on Wednesday in Kathmandu, hours after his record-breaking climb.
He spoke about the recent surge in luxury expeditions, the use of xenon gas for climbs and how climate change is radically altering the future of the mountain. This conversation has been condensed and edited for clarity.
Congratulations on your 31st climb. How are you feeling?
I'm proud of this achievement. As a guide, I fulfilled the long-cherished dreams of climbers to stand atop the world's highest point. I'm happy that I fulfilled their dreams this year as well.
This climb was a bit difficult because of harsh weather conditions. In my experience, over the last two or three years, climbing the mountain has become more difficult.
How so?
Changes are visible in the entire mountain region, not just Everest. It's because of climate change. Snow is melting faster than expected, and that has made climbing more difficult and riskier.
In the early days, at Camp II [a higher elevation on the mountain], we could walk over ice until the first week of June. We never saw streams coming down from that area. But on Tuesday, one of our fellow guides drowned because melting ice created a stream there. It was up to my waist.
What I fear is that, if this continues at the same rate, there will be no snow on the mountains in the next 10 to 15 years.
Because of the increased risks, the number of Sherpas climbing the mountain is dwindling. Foreign climbers may not come if expeditions become risker. If climbers don't come, guides won't have jobs, and there will also be no royalties for the government of Nepal.
I think eventually there will be no Sherpas to guide clients and no snow will exist.
What are the other big changes you've seen during your career?
Climbing used to be purely an adventurer's game. Decades ago, they used small tents. These days, some of them use luxury tents. Huge dome tents are used to keep climbers warm. Generators are used for light and to keep them warm.
In the early days, climbers used to climb even without food for a day or two. Or we used to survive with just the water from the mountains. These days, climbers get the food of their choice. Still, some of them complain about its taste.
I don't think some climbers are here for adventure. Some seem to be here for entertainment or to have a party in the mountains. It's not good for mountaineering.
This year, some used xenon gas to climb Everest in less than a week. How do you feel about its use to climb the mountain?
I heard about the use of xenon gas, but it's quite new for all of us.
It will take at least a few years to research this gas. Only then can we understand its impact on climbing.
What are the biggest lessons you've learned over the years?
We should understand the value of life. Taking clients to the summit is not the ultimate success; bringing them safely back to the base of the mountain is more important. Reuniting clients with their families is the greatest achievement.
How do you feel about the future of climbing Everest?
I don't see a future in climbing. For example, I'm not asking my son to work as a mountain guide. Sons or grandsons of other Sherpa families are also not joining the profession.
We have faced greater risks over time, and we don't want to bring our children into this career. Younger generations are no longer interested in working as climbing guides.
Because of that, I think there will be an acute shortage of Sherpas working as climbing guides. Foreign climbers will have to go up without Sherpas.
Should we drop them near the top of the mountain with helicopters so they can try to push to the summit from that point on their own? That's a possible scenario. When you don't have Sherpas to lead expeditions, that's the alternative.
Orange background

Try Our AI Features

Explore what Daily8 AI can do for you:

Comments

No comments yet...

Related Articles

Chinese climber dies after summiting world's second-highest peak, K2
Chinese climber dies after summiting world's second-highest peak, K2

Associated Press

time12 hours ago

  • Associated Press

Chinese climber dies after summiting world's second-highest peak, K2

GILGIT, Pakistan (AP) — A Chinese mountaineer has died after being hit by falling rocks while descending from the world's second-highest peak in northern Pakistan, officials said Wednesday. Guan Jing was struck on Tuesday while coming down from K2, a day after reaching the summit with a group of climbers, said Faizullah Faraq, a spokesman for the regional government of Gilgit-Baltistan. Faraq said efforts were underway to retrieve her body. The Pakistan Alpine Club confirmed her death and said she had successfully reached the summit on Monday. K2, which rises 8,611 meters (28,251 feet) above sea level in the Karakoram range, is regarded as one of the most dangerous mountains to climb because of its steep slopes, unpredictable weather and frequent rockfalls. Pakistan is home to several top mountain peaks, and climbers flock from all over the world to attempt to scale them. The latest death comes two weeks after German mountaineer and Olympic gold medalist Laura Dahlmeier died while attempting another peak in the region.

The Behavioral Economics Battle Lurking In EPA's Endangerment Finding Repeal
The Behavioral Economics Battle Lurking In EPA's Endangerment Finding Repeal

Forbes

time3 days ago

  • Forbes

The Behavioral Economics Battle Lurking In EPA's Endangerment Finding Repeal

The EPA's 2009 Endangerment Finding was the agency's formal determination that greenhouse gases endanger public health and welfare. Ever since, it has served as the legal foundation for EPA climate regulations. Without this finding, EPA lacks Clean Air Act authority to regulate greenhouse gas emissions. The Trump administration's EPA has now proposed to repeal the Endangerment Finding, along with the agency's greenhouse gas standards for light, medium, and heavy-duty vehicles that depend on it. In the agency's announcement, EPA justifies the repeal by citing the severe economic burdens of its existing rules, including over $1 trillion in compliance costs. As the agency moves to dismantle the Endangerment Finding, another battleground has opened up that has received less attention. That fight is about whether regulators should trust consumers' preferences or instead attempt to 'correct' them. The outcome of this debate could swing the measured benefits of climate rules by trillions of dollars. The Role of Regulatory Impact Analysis Because repealing the Endangerment Finding would also remove the legal basis for existing greenhouse gas standards for cars and trucks, EPA is required under longstanding executive orders to analyze the economic effects of that policy change. This requires the agency to tally the costs avoided and the benefits forgone from the action. To comply with these requirements, agencies prepare a regulatory impact analysis (RIA) whenever a rule or policy change is expected to have an annual economic effect of $100 million or more. RIA is a framework for identifying the expected consequences of a regulation, quantifying them where possible, and monetizing them when the data and methods allow. In the case of the Endangerment Finding repeal, that means examining how vehicle technology, fuel use, air pollution, and consumer welfare would differ with and without the greenhouse gas standards, and then converting any differences into dollar terms. In its draft RIA for the repeal action, EPA's core engineering-model estimate finds the repeal would yield net costs of roughly $260 billion (at a 3% discount rate, over the years 2027 to 2055). This traditional government approach counts fuel savings as a benefit to consumers, making the repeal appear costly since those savings would be lost. However, Appendix B of the RIA includes an alternative 'revealed preference' analysis that estimates net benefits of the repeal ranging from $3.05 trillion to $8.18 trillion. This set of estimates assumes that if consumers aren't voluntarily choosing more fuel-efficient vehicles, then forcing them to do so through regulations actually harms them. Any estimated savings, in that case, were pure fiction. By extension, so were many of the benefits of regulation. The Assumption of Revealed Preference Cost-benefit analysis aims to tally up the monetized social gains and losses from a policy. An economist adds up the 'private benefits' to particular individuals to arrive at a cumulative "social benefit" estimate for society as a whole. 'Revealed preference' is a concept central to this endeavor. By examining what people buy and how much they are willing to pay for different items and features, economists can estimate dollar values for different types of benefits and costs. This approach assumes that the observed willingness to pay of an individual reflects the value of a benefit to that person. This method has a major advantage in that it respects people's choices and doesn't involve analysts judging whether people's choices are good or bad; they merely accept that the choice made was what the individual preferred. The downside of this approach is that people don't always make decisions that accord with their own interests, or that of society. Fuel Savings Violate Revealed Preference For years, agencies writing fuel economy and energy efficiency rules have counted fuel and energy savings as a benefit of those rulemakings. When a consumer buys a more fuel-efficient car or appliance, they save money on gas or their utility bill. The government counts that as a significant benefit of a regulatory action phasing out less-efficient devices. This approach is valid if consumers genuinely underappreciate those savings when they buy a car or appliance. But if they already weigh fuel economy and energy efficiency against other attributes of a product before making a purchase, the savings are not a windfall benefit of the rulemaking. They're the flip side of losing other features the consumers value more. Appendix B of EPA's regulatory analysis relies on exactly that logic. If a consumer picks a gas-powered truck knowing it'll burn more fuel, they've made a trade they prefer. Forcing them into an EV to 'save' fuel costs is a net loss to them. Yet for many years, the government has treated this as a benefit. Behavioral Economics and the "Energy Efficiency Gap" Economists use the term 'energy efficiency gap' to describe the puzzling difference between the level of energy efficiency that appears cost-effective in theory and the lower level people actually choose in real life. For example, engineering calculations might show that spending $1,000 on better insulation, more efficient appliances, or a higher-MPG vehicle would pay for itself in a few years through lower utility or fuel bills. Yet, many consumers routinely forgo those investments. What explains the gap? One interpretation is that buyers are making biased, short-sighted decisions. This is the classic territory of "behavioral economics," a field focused on how real-world decisions often deviate from the assumptions of rational, optimizing behavior found in economists' models. Cognitive biases like hyperbolic discounting (placing too much weight on present rewards relative to future ones) or inattention (failing to notice or process fuel cost information) could lead people to under-invest in efficiency and leave money on the table. This perspective justifies counting the full value of 'missed' fuel savings as a regulatory benefit to the consumer, because the regulation is correcting their mistake. But there's another possibility, which is that the gap isn't a sign of bias at all, but instead a reflection of genuine trade-offs. A consumer might choose the lower-MPG car because they care more about acceleration, cargo space, style, or any number of attributes that are not captured in the fuel-savings calculations. An analyst who misinterprets the gap as a bias, when in fact the choice was based on a rational calculation, could force consumers into a less-preferred option and make them worse off. What's at Stake Separating bias from legitimate preferences is exceedingly difficult, and some would argue impossible. From the outside, the decision looks the same whether it's the product of error or preference. If we can't reliably distinguish between bias and preference, then the case for 'correcting' consumer choices becomes more about paternalism than empiricism. The stakes in this debate go beyond the Endangerment Finding. In many energy-efficiency rulemakings, 80 to 90 percent of the total monetized benefits come from the government's calculations of consumers' avoided energy costs. Environmental benefits to Americans are often in the low single-digit percentages. This means the overwhelming majority of the official benefit calculation hinges on the assumption that regulators can improve consumer welfare by steering people toward more efficient—and more expensive—products, even when buyers themselves would freely choose otherwise if left to decide on their own. This leaves economists in a quandary. Do they assume that observed market behavior is the best available measure of welfare, even if it sometimes reflects mistakes? Or do they override those choices based on models of what they think people should want if they made careful choices using all the available information? Or do they seek a middle ground, acknowledging that their models are often accurate but may also ignore important context-specific trade-offs? The answer to these questions determines whether a regulation's calculated benefits can be trusted. Private vs. Social Benefits Another complication relates to the difference between private and social benefits. Even when consumers make perfectly rational choices, what is in the interests of an individual doesn't always benefit society as a whole. When one person's gain imposes external costs on others, this can reduce, or even reverse, the net benefit for society. One obvious group affected by our purchasing decisions is future generations. It is easy to imagine future people might prefer that today's consumers forgo some luxuries in favor of greater savings and investment, which would improve living standards in the long run. But those intergenerational considerations are typically not reflected in market prices or, similarly, in economists' measures of revealed preference. In the context of energy and fuel economy, a dollar saved at the pump can be invested elsewhere in the economy, compounding to boost growth and future welfare. The enjoyment from a car feature like more horsepower or a panoramic sunroof can't be reinvested in the same way. So while a consumer may be better off paying more for those amenities, future generations probably will not be. From society's perspective, fuel and energy savings likely do represent social benefits for this reason, even when they don't compensate for their drawbacks from an individual's standpoint. A Rulemaking Worth Watching EPA's Endangerment Finding RIA pushes this debate forward by putting the revealed preference framework front-and-center, challenging the government's conventional inclusion of full lifetime fuel savings as a benefit. Whether that approach gains traction will matter well beyond this rulemaking. It's a core issue for how government evaluates climate and energy efficiency regulations generally. And it's another reason to watch closely how this already-high-stakes rulemaking unfolds.

'Better lives' urged as goal from productivity push
'Better lives' urged as goal from productivity push

Yahoo

time3 days ago

  • Yahoo

'Better lives' urged as goal from productivity push

Improving people's lives, not just economic outcomes, should be front and centre of the government's upcoming reform roundtable, an independent think tank says. Addressing climate change, inequality, the cost of living, housing affordability and environmental degradation should be the measure for success rather than increased economic activity for its own sake, the Centre for Policy Development said in a report. The contribution comes as employer groups, unions, civil society and politicians weigh in on what they want from Treasurer Jim Chalmers' productivity summit later in August. Amid the competing claims, the think tank's chief executive Andrew Hudson called for some perspective. "We shouldn't assume that productivity gains will automatically translate into better lives," he said. "If we want a stronger economy that actually delivers for people, we need to make that the explicit goal - not just a hopeful by-product." Mr Hudson called for the tax mix to be shifted away from income towards rents, consumption and wealth, improving funding and approvals for clean energy projects, and addressing productivity in the care sector. The report argued that productivity was poorly measured in sectors such as health and aged care, which led to worse outcomes for patients when operators sought to boost efficiency by cutting staff, for example. The recommendations come as the Productivity Commission prepares to release a report on upskilling Australia's workforce on Monday night - the fourth of five interim reports ahead of the August 19-21 roundtable. Prime Minister Anthony Albanese has tempered hopes major results from the roundtable will be implemented this term - comments portrayed by the opposition as a split with the treasurer. Deputy Prime Minister Richard Marles denied any disagreement between the pair, implying any tax changes would be brought to the next election. "They're on the same page," he told ABC's Insiders program on Sunday. "The tax policies that we have are what we took to the election. "But we need to be lifting productivity in this country and over the longer term, we need to have a clear eye as to how best to do that. "We're not seeking to constrain the ideas put forward at the roundtable next week." Error in retrieving data Sign in to access your portfolio Error in retrieving data

DOWNLOAD THE APP

Get Started Now: Download the App

Ready to dive into a world of global content with local flavor? Download Daily8 app today from your preferred app store and start exploring.
app-storeplay-store