logo
Cantwell, researchers lament Trump administrations calls to halve funding for National Science Foundation

Cantwell, researchers lament Trump administrations calls to halve funding for National Science Foundation

Yahoo21-05-2025

May 20—America's globally dominant position in scientific research could be jeopardized by the White House's drastic proposed cuts to the National Science Foundation's funding and staff, Sen. Maria Cantwell warned Monday at a round table with sector experts and engineers, including a WSU researcher focused on the integration of artificial intelligence in agriculture.
President Donald Trump recently called for a 55% cut in funding for the NSF, the independent agency of the federal government responsible for funding research and education into nonmedical sciences. It's a counterpart to the medical research-focused National Institutes for Health, for which Trump has also proposed cutting funding by 40%.
If the cuts are enacted, the NSF's budget would drop from $9 billion to about $4 billion at the start of the next fiscal year in October.
Many researchers were alarmed and argued such cuts could have long-ranging impacts on the country's security, industries and economy.
Based on a 2024 study of the long-term economic benefits of government funded R&D, University of Georgia professor John Drake recently wrote in a column in Forbes that these cuts would ultimately cost the U.S. economy $10 billion annually in unrealized gains.
The White House, meanwhile, has argued the cuts are part of a necessary realignment of government-funded scientific research, accompanied with an announcement earlier this month that the NSF would be majorly restructured and drastically reduce the number of funded programs. Instead, the agency has been directed to refocus its remaining funding to five key research priorities for the president: artificial intelligence, quantum information science, biotechnology, nuclear energy and translational science.
Michael Kratsios, the president's science and technology advisor, told the National Academy of Sciences on Sunday that a surge of research spending in the last 40 years has not seen an accompanying return on investment, echoing the president's call for more focused spending.
"More money has not meant more scientific discovery, and total dollars spent has not been a proxy for scientific impact," Kratsios said. "Spending more money on the wrong things is far worse than spending less money on the right things."
Cantwell and a number of researchers at Monday's roundtable said Kratsios misunderstood the value of the federal government's investments in cutting edge research that often takes decades to reach consumers.
"The Nobel Prize winner for developing the mRNA vaccine (Katalin Karikó) was judged to not be doing any kind of useful research for many years by a lot of her peers, so I don't think any one person can judge the value of research that NSF invests in," said Dr. Dean Chang, chief innovation officer and associate vice president for innovation and entrepreneurship and economic development at the University of Maryland.
Ananth Kalyanaraman is the interim director at Washington State University's School of Electrical Engineering and Computer Science and the director of AgAID, a USDA- and NSF-funded program to research the use of AI in agriculture.
The impact of NSF's cuts to WSU would be far-reaching, Kalyanaraman added, including into the school's research on aquaculture, health, power grids, cyber security and the integration of robotics and AI into several other sectors such as manufacturing and production, as well as his own research into agriculture.
"We are deeply concerned about the nearly $5 billion in cuts to NSF which will directly undercut this vital work and also our nation's ability to remain globally competitive," Kalyanaraman said Monday. "Critically, NSF funding also supports the development of future workforce, and without it, we'll fall behind in our ability to produce the much needed next generation of AI-ready graduates."
Francis Cordova, former director of NSF under both Presidents Trump and Barack Obama, said workforce development has been a vital priority for the agency that is now at risk.
"Industry representatives often tell me that arguably the most important investment NSF makes is in the workforce training of STEM talent," Cordova said. "Arguably the most important part of our economic security, our national security and the relatively high standard of living we enjoy in this country is due to government funding of basic research in the scientific workforce."
While budget cuts to the agency have not yet been approved by Congress, the White House has been shaking up the NSF for months.
The NSF has announced it will lay off an unspecified number of its 1,700-person workforce and slash the number of academic researchers it employs to help guide what research to fund from 368 to 70 by June 9. The agency, along with NIH and the Department of Energy, also attempted earlier this year to cap the percentage of grant funds that could cover "indirect research" costs such as equipment, facilities and administrators, though those decisions have been tied up in legal battles.
Since January, NSF has terminated more than 1,500 grants worth more than a billion dollars, Cantwell claimed Monday.
In April, all NSF grants were frozen, reportedly under the direction of the Department of Government Efficiency, while the Elon Musk-led agency reviewed grants for possible diversity, equity and inclusion-related grants for termination.
"DEI initiatives, in particular, degrade our scientific enterprise," Kratsios told the National Academy of Sciences on Sunday. "DEI represents an existential threat to the real diversity of thought that forms the foundation of the scientific community."

Orange background

Try Our AI Features

Explore what Daily8 AI can do for you:

Comments

No comments yet...

Related Articles

UMaine professor wins $1M grant to take a new look at old plants
UMaine professor wins $1M grant to take a new look at old plants

Yahoo

time8 hours ago

  • Yahoo

UMaine professor wins $1M grant to take a new look at old plants

Jun. 9—A University of Maine professor has won a $1 million National Science Foundation award to develop faster, cheaper ways to study plants by developing technology to analyze the 390 million specimens already stored in archived collections around the world. Jose "Dudu" Meireles, an assistant professor of plant evolution and systematics, will use the grant to develop an open source computer model that integrates genetic analysis and spectral imaging to assess the chemical makeup and function of collected plant leaves, ranging from nitrogen levels to defense mechanisms. The five-year grant supports Meireles' plan to unlock centuries of hidden data stored in the world's herbariums, which hold vast archives of preserved plant specimens. Studying collected plants will save time and money by dispensing with a lot of field work and lab tests while protecting the plants themselves from destruction. "It's sometimes hard to see the value in these places because it's a giant room full of dried plants," said Meireles, a Brazilian native who joined the University of Maine in 2019. "But the bottom line is we can do a lot of cutting-edge science using those specimens." Meireles' approach combines advanced computing with a technique called spectral phenotyping, which uses light to measure plant traits much like airport scanners do with luggage. Multiple traits can be measured with one test without spending time and money to find the plants in the field or running multiple laboratory tests. The result? A dramatic increase in the speed and scale of biodiversity research. If his methods are widely adopted, Meireles estimates that scientists could triple the amount of data they collect on plant function each year. He plans to teach these to University of Maine undergraduates in a class starting in the fall of 2027. Students at UMaine will work alongside him in the lab, gaining hands-on experience with cutting-edge tools. The Meireles laboratory will also collaborate with other UMaine departments to produce a public biodiversity exhibit, aiming to bridge the gap between science and society, that will be displayed at Coastal Maine Botanical Gardens. Meireles said his methods won't eliminate the need for field work, but instead will complement that boots-on-the-ground research to help understand how whole plant communities in an area adapt to environmental change over time. Just next week he plans to hike up Mount Washington to collect field measurements. He plans to hold workshops across the U.S. and Latin America to help train other plant researchers on how to use the computer models and spectral analysis to plumb the secrets of the collections they already have on hand. Over 100 people will have had the opportunity to learn the new methods by the end of the grant. "This will make biodiversity science faster, cheaper and more globally comprehensive," Meireles said. Meireles' team will partner with curators and researchers from New York Botanical Gardens' Steere Herbarium, The Field Museum in Chicago and Coastal Maine Botanical Gardens in Boothbay and herbaria in Columbia and Brazil to develop protocols for the work, publicize it and train others on how to do it. "Every herbarium specimen has a story to tell, even specimens that are decades or centuries old," said Emily Sessa, the director of the Steere Herbarium. "This work will create an exciting new avenue for herbarium collections to inform us about biodiversity and new tools for collecting data on important plant traits at large scales." The implications stretch far beyond academia. Industries from agriculture to pharmaceuticals rely on plant-based products and services. A deeper understanding of how plants function and adapt, especially in the face of climate change, could lead to new crops, medicines and conservation strategies. "There are over 300,000 species of flowering plants, and we only know how a tiny fraction work," Meireles said. "They hold a huge library of solutions that evolution came up with over a very long time. And so far, we've only been able to harness a tiny portion of that." With this new funding, Meireles plans to show just how much those dried herbarium plants still have to teach us. Copy the Story Link

How Honesty Won This Economist a Nobel Prize
How Honesty Won This Economist a Nobel Prize

Scientific American

time13 hours ago

  • Scientific American

How Honesty Won This Economist a Nobel Prize

You're at a blind auction, and the rules are simple. If you see something that you want, place a secret bid, and the item will sell to the highest bidder at their stated price. You would love to take home that new laptop or concert ticket or dinner with a local celebrity, but how much should you bid? Even if you can perfectly quantify what each item is worth to you, you still face a dilemma: You have no idea how others will bid. Should you bid close to your personal maximum and risk overpaying if everybody else bids low? Or should you bid low yourself and hope to get lucky? A clever yet simple tweak to the rules of the auction eliminates this strategic guessing game and replaces it with an incentive rarely found in money games: honesty. The tweak has inspired real-world auctions that power e-commerce and helped earn its inventor a Nobel Prize in economics. The branch of economics known as auction theory calls the scenario above a first-price sealed-bid auction. Sealed-bid means bids are private, and first-price indicates the winner pays the highest price among all of the bids. In 1961 Columbia University professor of economics William Vickrey proposed an ingenious alternative. In his version, the highest bidder still wins but only pays the amount of the second-highest bid. This peculiar twist has a radical effect on the bidders' incentives. In a first-price sealed-bid auction, bidders are incentivized to shade their bids—that is, to offer less than what they consider the object's true value to avoid overpaying. But in a second -price sealed-bid auction (also called a Vickrey auction) the best move would be to bid an amount equivalent to the object's worth to you. No game-playing is required. On supporting science journalism If you're enjoying this article, consider supporting our award-winning journalism by subscribing. By purchasing a subscription you are helping to ensure the future of impactful stories about the discoveries and ideas shaping our world today. Suppose you'd pay at most $100 for a concert ticket. In the first-price auction, it never makes sense to bid more than $100, because even if you won the ticket, you would, in effect, lose money by paying more for it than it's worth to you. Bidding exactly $100 doesn't help because at best you break even. The ideal bid is the smallest one under $100 that still wins. If you knew the next-highest bid would be $70, then bidding $70.01 would win you the ticket and net you $29.99 of value. Unfortunately this strategy requires predicting the behavior of others, which is difficult in practice. Why does the second-price auction incentivize honesty? You might feel tempted to bid a lot, say $500, to secure a win while only paying the second-highest bid. Somebody else, though, may have the same bright idea, leaving you on the hook to pay way more than your value for the ticket. If this doesn't happen, and the second-highest bid is under $100, then you could have achieved the same outcome by bidding honestly at $100 without the risk. You also shouldn't underbid. If you win, then you would have won anyway with an honest bid (and paid the same amount). But if you lose to a bid of less than $100, then you miss out on a deal you would have gladly taken. Vickrey auctions not only reward honesty but also ensure that the item goes to the person who values it most (assuming everybody plays rationally). First-price auctions lack this guarantee because strategic underbidding with incomplete information about other players may result in someone with a lower valuation winning. Both of the auction types discussed so far involve quietly sealing a single bid in an envelope. But when many of us picture an auction, we imagine the so-called English auction where a speed-talking, gavel-wielding auctioneer shouts increasing prices as bidders raise paddles to vie for the prize. When you hear 'Going once, going twice— sold!' the last person who raised their paddle wins the item at whatever price they bid. The less common, though equally intriguing, 'Dutch auction' flips the concept. Here the auctioneer begins with a sky-high price that nobody would pay and gradually lowers it until one person jumps in to buy on the spot. Although the real-time, dynamic nature of English and Dutch auctions make them appear unrelated to the sealed-bid models, an unexpected correspondence unites them. Recall that the sealed-bid auctions elicited different strategies from buyers depending on whether they expected to pay the highest bid amount (in which case they should predict the highest competing bid and offer a hair above it) or the second-highest (in which case they should bid their honest value for the item). Amazingly, English and Dutch auctions incentivize these same strategies. Care to guess which one maps to which? In a Dutch auction (where the price descends), you don't want to stop the descent right at your honest value, because you would pay your maximum. Instead you want to predict the highest bid that's not yours and cut in just above it—exactly the same thought process as a first-price sealed-bid auction. English auctions (where the price ascends), on the other hand, incentivize honesty. You're willing to pay every new price up until your true value for the item, at which point you drop out. The winner in an English auction essentially pays the second-highest bidder's stopping point, much like in a second-price sealed-bid auction. The similarities among the four auction types run even deeper. So far we've focused on buyer strategies but have neglected the seller's perspective. Which auction should a seller conduct to make the most money? Here comes another surprising twist from auction theory: they're all equivalent. The revenue equivalence theorem states that, under certain idealized mathematical conditions, a seller should expect the same revenue under all four auction types. The specific assumptions are too in the weeds to list here, but they include things such as rational bidders who are neither risk-averse nor risk-loving and who know some information about how the other players arrive at their valuations. Why do researchers study four types of auctions if they all yield the same financial outcome? It turns out the key differences are less about theory and more about practical considerations. For example, Dutch auctions work best for perishable items because they resolve quickly—only one person ever needs to bid for a sale. For instance, Royal FloraHolland hosts the largest flower auction in the world. Every weekday Dutch-style auction clocks tick down prices for floriculture products, and the first bidder takes them home at that moment's price. We've assumed so far that buyers know their personal valuation of the item for sale. But what if nobody, including the seller, knows its true worth? In these contexts, English auctions prove especially useful, because their open, incremental bidding reveals information about others' valuations. This dynamic helps explain their popularity for rare goods like art. While Vickrey auctions, in their purest form, haven't proliferated (except in stamp auctions, where their dominance dates back to the late 1800s), the second-price concept has inspired hybrid models in widespread use today. The most notable example is eBay. A potential buyer privately tells the site their maximum bid, and then eBay automatically increases their offer just enough to outbid competitors, up to that maximum. The winner pays slightly more than the second-highest bid. Researchers continue to study questions about the real-world implications of different auction designs: Which ones elicit the most fiscally rational behavior in practice? Which types resist harmful collusion? And which systems feel the best to win or the worst to lose? Vickrey won an economics Nobel in 1996 in part for his contributions to auction theory. He stands out among laureates as the man who proved that sometimes honesty is the best policy.

DOWNLOAD THE APP

Get Started Now: Download the App

Ready to dive into the world of global news and events? Download our app today from your preferred app store and start exploring.
app-storeplay-store