
The seismic impact of Pillar Two on global economies
The source of this new instability is not a financial crisis or a geopolitical conflict, but a landmark international agreement known as Pillar Two. Developed by the OECD, this framework introduces a global minimum corporate tax of 15 percent on MNEs with revenues above €750 million. While the concept may sound simple, its implementation is a profound macroeconomic event, fundamentally altering the calculus of investment, reshaping national tax policies, and challenging the very notion of tax sovereignty.
This article explores the deep-seated economic tremors caused by Pillar Two - from the direct impact on national tax revenues to the indirect shifts in investment and economic policy - and what they mean for the future of the global economy.
The new tax order: A seismic shift in the global rulebook
To understand the tremors, one must first grasp the mechanics of Pillar Two. It is not a new tax in the traditional sense, but rather a complex system of interlocking rules designed to ensure MNEs pay a minimum 15 percent tax on their profits in every jurisdiction they operate. The core of the framework rests on three key rules:
1. The income inclusion rule (IIR): This is the primary rule. It requires a parent company in a GloBE-implementing jurisdiction to pay a 'top-up tax' on the low-taxed income of its foreign subsidiaries.
2. The under-taxed profits rule (UTPR): This is a backstop to the IIR. It comes into play when the parent company is in a non-GloBE jurisdiction. It denies deductions or makes an equivalent adjustment to the tax of the MNE's entities in other implementing jurisdictions to collect the top-up tax.
3. The qualified domestic minimum top-up tax (QDMTT): This allows a country to impose its own domestic minimum tax to collect any top-up tax on the low-taxed income within its borders, ensuring the tax revenue remains within its own economy. Together, these rules create a powerful incentive for MNEs to pay tax at the 15 percent minimum rate wherever they operate. The genius - and the tremor - lies in the fact that if a low-tax country does not collect the top-up tax, another country will. This effectively ends the 'race to the bottom' by making the tax rate floor a global standard.
Direct tremors: The end of tax sovereignty as we knew it
The most immediate and direct tremor caused by Pillar Two is its challenge to the long-held principle of tax sovereignty. For decades, a country's right to set its own corporate tax rates was seen as a fundamental aspect of its economic policy. A nation could choose to have a low rate to attract foreign direct investment (FDI), and that was its sovereign prerogative. Pillar Two fundamentally alters this. By introducing a global minimum tax, it effectively establishes a floor below which countries cannot drop their effective tax rates without another nation claiming the difference.
This does not mean countries are legally forbidden from having a tax rate below 15 percent; rather, it means there is a powerful economic disincentive to do so. A low-tax jurisdiction that chooses to maintain a low rate (eg, 5 percent) will simply see its tax revenues collected by the parent company's jurisdiction via the IIR. This shift presents a critical policy dilemma.
Low-tax jurisdictions, many of which have built their economies around attracting foreign capital through tax incentives, are now faced with a stark choice:
• Implement a QDMTT: By introducing a domestic minimum tax, they can raise their effective tax rate to 15 percent on local profits and collect the top-up tax themselves. This allows them to retain the revenue that would have otherwise gone to another country.
Do nothing: They can choose not to implement a QDMTT, but in doing so, they give up the right to collect that top-up tax, effectively subsidizing the tax bases of other countries. This dynamic creates a powerful macroeconomic tremor. It forces nations to re-evaluate their entire economic model. Low-tax hubs are now scrambling to find new ways to attract investment that do not rely solely on a low tax rate. The QDMTT, which is expected to be widely adopted, is the most visible sign of this tremor - countries are proactively raising their tax rates to 15 percent to defend their tax base. This is a global, coordinated retreat from decades of tax competition.
Indirect Tremors: Reshaping investment and capital flows
The indirect economic tremors from Pillar Two are just as significant, and they will likely be felt over a longer period. With the removal of tax-rate arbitrage as a primary driver of investment, MNEs will be forced to reconsider where and why they invest.
1) A new calculus for FDI: The primary rationale for placing operations in a low-tax jurisdiction will be significantly diminished. This means that other factors will become more important in MNEs' investment decisions. Countries with a skilled workforce, robust infrastructure, political stability, and access to key markets will become more attractive. Investment that was previously routed through low-tax jurisdictions may now flow directly to a country with a more compelling economic proposition, even if its headline tax rate is higher than 15 percent. This could lead to a redirection of global capital flows, with potential winners and losers.
2) Restructuring of tax incentives: Nations that once used low tax rates to attract business will now need to find new ways to incentivize investment. Instead of rate-based incentives, we can expect a shift toward more substance-based incentives.
This could include: R&D tax credits: Offering tax credits for research and development activities.
• Capital investment subsidies: Providing grants or subsidies for investments in new plants, equipment, or technology.
• Workforce development: Providing incentives for companies that invest in training and upskilling local employees. These incentives are less susceptible to the GloBE Rules and can be more effective at generating real economic activity. The tremor here is a fundamental re-engineering of tax policy, moving it from a purely financial tool to one more directly tied to substantive economic development. The Impact on GDP Growth:
The economic models predicting the impact of Pillar Two are complex and varied, but they generally suggest a potential slowdown in global GDP growth, particularly in the short term. The new compliance costs for MNEs, the re-routing of investment, and the potential for increased tax burdens could have a slight dampening effect. However, in the long term, a more level playing field could foster fairer competition and more efficient allocation of capital, leading to more sustainable growth. The tremor, in this sense, is a necessary corrective to a global system that had become too distorted by tax planning.
The path forward
Challenges and opportunities implementing Pillar Two is a monumental task, and the path forward is not without its challenges. For many countries, it requires a complete overhaul of their domestic tax laws and a new level of cooperation between tax administrations. The compliance burden on MNEs, particularly in the initial years, is also significant. However, the framework presents immense opportunities.
• Recaptured tax revenues: For countries that implement a QDMTT, there is an opportunity to recapture billions in tax revenues that were previously lost to tax competition. These new revenues could be used to fund public services, invest in infrastructure, or reduce other taxes.
• A fairer playing field: By ending the 'race to the bottom,' Pillar Two levels the playing field for domestic companies that could not compete with the low tax rates offered to foreign MNEs. This could foster a more vibrant and competitive local business environment. The final outcome of these macroeconomic tremors will depend on how nations respond. Will they embrace the new reality and use it as an opportunity to build more sustainable, resilient, and equitable economies? Or will they resist the change, clinging to outdated policies that no longer serve them?
A new dawn for global tax Pillar Two is more than a tax rule; it is a global economic tremor that marks the end of an era. It challenges a decades-long tradition of tax competition, forces nations to re-examine their economic models, and sets the stage for a new, more coordinated approach to international tax. The shockwaves are already being felt in the form of tax reforms, shifts in investment strategies, and a new sense of urgency among policymakers.
The era of macroeconomic tremors is here, and it is defined not by a crisis, but by a profound change in the very rules of the game. For all the complexity and challenges, the promise of a fairer, more stable global tax system is a prize worth pursuing. The journey to a new equilibrium will be long and uneven, but the direction is now clear: towards a world where all MNEs pay a fair share, and the benefits of globalization are more evenly shared.
NOTE: Hassan M Abdulrahim is a Senior Instructor (Business) at Canadian College Kuwait and CEO & Co-founder of Visionary Consulting Company

Try Our AI Features
Explore what Daily8 AI can do for you:
Comments
No comments yet...
Related Articles

Kuwait Times
2 days ago
- Kuwait Times
The seismic impact of Pillar Two on global economies
In the complex, interconnected world of international finance, global stability has long been influenced by a quiet but powerful force: tax competition. For decades, nations engaged in a 'race to the bottom,' using ever-lower corporate tax rates to lure multinational enterprises (MNEs) and their prized capital. This long-standing paradigm, however, is now facing a seismic shift, and the tremors are reverberating through economies worldwide. The source of this new instability is not a financial crisis or a geopolitical conflict, but a landmark international agreement known as Pillar Two. Developed by the OECD, this framework introduces a global minimum corporate tax of 15 percent on MNEs with revenues above €750 million. While the concept may sound simple, its implementation is a profound macroeconomic event, fundamentally altering the calculus of investment, reshaping national tax policies, and challenging the very notion of tax sovereignty. This article explores the deep-seated economic tremors caused by Pillar Two - from the direct impact on national tax revenues to the indirect shifts in investment and economic policy - and what they mean for the future of the global economy. The new tax order: A seismic shift in the global rulebook To understand the tremors, one must first grasp the mechanics of Pillar Two. It is not a new tax in the traditional sense, but rather a complex system of interlocking rules designed to ensure MNEs pay a minimum 15 percent tax on their profits in every jurisdiction they operate. The core of the framework rests on three key rules: 1. The income inclusion rule (IIR): This is the primary rule. It requires a parent company in a GloBE-implementing jurisdiction to pay a 'top-up tax' on the low-taxed income of its foreign subsidiaries. 2. The under-taxed profits rule (UTPR): This is a backstop to the IIR. It comes into play when the parent company is in a non-GloBE jurisdiction. It denies deductions or makes an equivalent adjustment to the tax of the MNE's entities in other implementing jurisdictions to collect the top-up tax. 3. The qualified domestic minimum top-up tax (QDMTT): This allows a country to impose its own domestic minimum tax to collect any top-up tax on the low-taxed income within its borders, ensuring the tax revenue remains within its own economy. Together, these rules create a powerful incentive for MNEs to pay tax at the 15 percent minimum rate wherever they operate. The genius - and the tremor - lies in the fact that if a low-tax country does not collect the top-up tax, another country will. This effectively ends the 'race to the bottom' by making the tax rate floor a global standard. Direct tremors: The end of tax sovereignty as we knew it The most immediate and direct tremor caused by Pillar Two is its challenge to the long-held principle of tax sovereignty. For decades, a country's right to set its own corporate tax rates was seen as a fundamental aspect of its economic policy. A nation could choose to have a low rate to attract foreign direct investment (FDI), and that was its sovereign prerogative. Pillar Two fundamentally alters this. By introducing a global minimum tax, it effectively establishes a floor below which countries cannot drop their effective tax rates without another nation claiming the difference. This does not mean countries are legally forbidden from having a tax rate below 15 percent; rather, it means there is a powerful economic disincentive to do so. A low-tax jurisdiction that chooses to maintain a low rate (eg, 5 percent) will simply see its tax revenues collected by the parent company's jurisdiction via the IIR. This shift presents a critical policy dilemma. Low-tax jurisdictions, many of which have built their economies around attracting foreign capital through tax incentives, are now faced with a stark choice: • Implement a QDMTT: By introducing a domestic minimum tax, they can raise their effective tax rate to 15 percent on local profits and collect the top-up tax themselves. This allows them to retain the revenue that would have otherwise gone to another country. Do nothing: They can choose not to implement a QDMTT, but in doing so, they give up the right to collect that top-up tax, effectively subsidizing the tax bases of other countries. This dynamic creates a powerful macroeconomic tremor. It forces nations to re-evaluate their entire economic model. Low-tax hubs are now scrambling to find new ways to attract investment that do not rely solely on a low tax rate. The QDMTT, which is expected to be widely adopted, is the most visible sign of this tremor - countries are proactively raising their tax rates to 15 percent to defend their tax base. This is a global, coordinated retreat from decades of tax competition. Indirect Tremors: Reshaping investment and capital flows The indirect economic tremors from Pillar Two are just as significant, and they will likely be felt over a longer period. With the removal of tax-rate arbitrage as a primary driver of investment, MNEs will be forced to reconsider where and why they invest. 1) A new calculus for FDI: The primary rationale for placing operations in a low-tax jurisdiction will be significantly diminished. This means that other factors will become more important in MNEs' investment decisions. Countries with a skilled workforce, robust infrastructure, political stability, and access to key markets will become more attractive. Investment that was previously routed through low-tax jurisdictions may now flow directly to a country with a more compelling economic proposition, even if its headline tax rate is higher than 15 percent. This could lead to a redirection of global capital flows, with potential winners and losers. 2) Restructuring of tax incentives: Nations that once used low tax rates to attract business will now need to find new ways to incentivize investment. Instead of rate-based incentives, we can expect a shift toward more substance-based incentives. This could include: R&D tax credits: Offering tax credits for research and development activities. • Capital investment subsidies: Providing grants or subsidies for investments in new plants, equipment, or technology. • Workforce development: Providing incentives for companies that invest in training and upskilling local employees. These incentives are less susceptible to the GloBE Rules and can be more effective at generating real economic activity. The tremor here is a fundamental re-engineering of tax policy, moving it from a purely financial tool to one more directly tied to substantive economic development. The Impact on GDP Growth: The economic models predicting the impact of Pillar Two are complex and varied, but they generally suggest a potential slowdown in global GDP growth, particularly in the short term. The new compliance costs for MNEs, the re-routing of investment, and the potential for increased tax burdens could have a slight dampening effect. However, in the long term, a more level playing field could foster fairer competition and more efficient allocation of capital, leading to more sustainable growth. The tremor, in this sense, is a necessary corrective to a global system that had become too distorted by tax planning. The path forward Challenges and opportunities implementing Pillar Two is a monumental task, and the path forward is not without its challenges. For many countries, it requires a complete overhaul of their domestic tax laws and a new level of cooperation between tax administrations. The compliance burden on MNEs, particularly in the initial years, is also significant. However, the framework presents immense opportunities. • Recaptured tax revenues: For countries that implement a QDMTT, there is an opportunity to recapture billions in tax revenues that were previously lost to tax competition. These new revenues could be used to fund public services, invest in infrastructure, or reduce other taxes. • A fairer playing field: By ending the 'race to the bottom,' Pillar Two levels the playing field for domestic companies that could not compete with the low tax rates offered to foreign MNEs. This could foster a more vibrant and competitive local business environment. The final outcome of these macroeconomic tremors will depend on how nations respond. Will they embrace the new reality and use it as an opportunity to build more sustainable, resilient, and equitable economies? Or will they resist the change, clinging to outdated policies that no longer serve them? A new dawn for global tax Pillar Two is more than a tax rule; it is a global economic tremor that marks the end of an era. It challenges a decades-long tradition of tax competition, forces nations to re-examine their economic models, and sets the stage for a new, more coordinated approach to international tax. The shockwaves are already being felt in the form of tax reforms, shifts in investment strategies, and a new sense of urgency among policymakers. The era of macroeconomic tremors is here, and it is defined not by a crisis, but by a profound change in the very rules of the game. For all the complexity and challenges, the promise of a fairer, more stable global tax system is a prize worth pursuing. The journey to a new equilibrium will be long and uneven, but the direction is now clear: towards a world where all MNEs pay a fair share, and the benefits of globalization are more evenly shared. NOTE: Hassan M Abdulrahim is a Senior Instructor (Business) at Canadian College Kuwait and CEO & Co-founder of Visionary Consulting Company

Kuwait Times
13-08-2025
- Kuwait Times
Kuwait population reaches 5.099 million; Budget revenues could hit KD 18.276bn
Kuwaitis make up 75.6% of employees in public sector KUWAIT: The total population in Kuwait reached approximately 5.099 million people by the end of June 2025, marking a growth of about 2.2 percent—or an absolute increase of around 111,000 people—compared to the end of 2024 when the population was 4.988 million, according to the data released by the Public Authority for Civil Information. The PACI has released the latest detailed data on population and labor statistics as of the end of June 2025. The proportion of Kuwaitis in the total population also dropped— from about 31.7 percent at the end of the first half of 2024 to around 30.4 percent according to the latest figures. The number of Kuwaiti males, at approximately 776.7 thousand, slightly exceeds that of Kuwaiti females, at around 773.9 thousand. Meanwhile, the number of non-Kuwaiti residents increased by about 189.3 thousand people, representing a growth rate of approximately 5.6 percent, bringing their total to around 3.548 million. The compound annual growth rate (CAGR) of the non-Kuwaiti population from 2015 to June 2025 was about 2.0 percent. The total number of workers in Kuwait reached approximately 3.142 million, representing about 61.6 percent of the total population. For Kuwaiti citizens, the employment-to-population ratio stood at about 31.7 percent of the total Kuwaiti population. Notably, the percentage of employed non-Kuwaitis out of the total non-Kuwaiti population was around 74.7 percent. When compared to the end of June 2024, the share of Kuwaiti workers within the total workforce in Kuwait decreased from about 16.6 percent to approximately 15.6 percent in June 2025. Additionally, the proportion of female workers among the total Kuwaiti workforce declined to around 49.3 percent by the end of the first half of the current year, down from 51.2 percent in June 2024. Female workers made up around 30.3 percent of the total workforce in Kuwait. The number of employed Kuwaiti nationals declined by approximately 15.2 thousand, bringing the total to around 491.1 thousand workers, down from about 506.4 thousand at the end of June 2024. Of these, about 392.9 thousand were employed in the government sector, accounting for 80.0 percent of all working Kuwaitis. This figure differs from the 83.8 percent reported by the CSB, both entities being government institutions, which may be due to the inclusion of unemployed individuals or those on waiting lists in the latter's figures. It is believed that the number of openly unemployed Kuwaitis slightly increased to around 30.7 thousand individuals, representing approximately 6.2 percent of the total Kuwaiti labor force by the end of June 2025, compared to about 29.9 thousand or 5.9 percent at the end of June 2024. The total number of workers (both Kuwaiti and non-Kuwaiti) in the government sector reached about 520 thousand, which accounts for roughly 16.5 percent of the total population. Kuwaitis made up approximately 75.6 percent of all employees in the public sector. Kuwait oil price edges up By the end of July 2025, the fourth month of the current fiscal year 2025/2026 had concluded. The average price of Kuwaiti oil per barrel for July was around $71.4, an increase of $1.5 per barrel or by 2.2 percent compared to the June's average of $69.9 per barrel. It was also higher by $3.4 per barrel or by 5.0 percent, compared to the new assumed price in the current budget which is set at $68 per barrel. When comparing this figure to the approved expenditures of KD 24.538 billion, it is likely that the general budget for the current fiscal year 2025/2026 will record a deficit of KD 6.262 billion. However, the dominant factor remains the developments in oil revenues and the potential for savings in expenditures. Furthermore, the average price of Kuwaiti oil per barrel for the elapsed period of the current fiscal year stood at $69, that is lower by $10.7 or by-13.4 percent compared to the average price per barrel of the previous fiscal year 2024/2025, which was around $79.7. It is also lower by $21.5 or by 23.7 percent, compared to the breakeven price in the current budget at $90.5, according to estimates by the Ministry of Finance and following the suspension of the 10 percent deduction from total revenues for the Future Generations Reserve. It is assumed that Kuwait generated oil revenues of KD 1.352 billion in July. Assuming that production levels and prices remain unchanged, an assumption that may not hold, total oil revenues for the entire current fiscal year are expected to reach KD 15.350 billion after deducting production costs. This figure is around KD 45 million higher than the estimated amount in the current fiscal year's budget, which is at KD 15.305 billion. With the addition of around KD 2.926 billion in non-oil revenues, the total budget revenues for the current fiscal year would amount to KD 18.276 billion. An announcement was made on July 22, 2025, regarding the actual budget deficit (the final account) for the previous fiscal year 2024/2025, which amounted to KD 1.056 billion. However, the detailed figures of that final account have not yet been published, making it difficult to analyze the situation.

Kuwait Times
13-08-2025
- Kuwait Times
The many elections available to MNEs under GloBE rules
Strategic flexibility in the era of global minimum taxation: Kuwait's commitment to implementing the OECD's BEPS Pillar Two initiative, encapsulated in Law 157/2024 and its executive regulations, marks a significant shift in corporate taxation. While the overarching goal of a 15 percent global minimum tax is firm, the intricate GloBE Model Rules are not entirely rigid. Recognizing the diverse operational realities of multinational enterprises (MNEs), the rules incorporate a series of 'Elections'. These elections offer MNEs a degree of flexibility, allowing them to choose specific accounting or tax treatments for various items within the GloBE calculations. They are critical tools for MNEs to manage their compliance burden, align their global minimum tax outcomes with their economic reality, and in some cases, mitigate unexpected top-up tax liabilities. Understanding these elections is essential for MNEs operating in Kuwait as they prepare to navigate this new tax landscape. Why Elections? The rationale behind flexibility The primary reasons for introducing elections into the GloBE Rules include: 1. Reducing compliance burden: Some elections simplify complex calculations or allow MNEs to leverage existing data more easily. 2. Addressing asymmetries: Financial accounting rules and domestic tax laws can treat certain items, like fair value changes or stock-based compensation, differently, leading to potential 'asymmetries' that might distort the GloBE Effective Tax Rate (ETR). Elections help to align the GloBE outcome with the MNE's economic substance or domestic tax treatment. 3. Mitigating unintended top-up tax: By allowing MNEs to adopt certain treatments, elections can help prevent situations where an MNE with genuine economic activity might inadvertently trigger a top-up tax. 4. Promoting policy objectives: Some elections align with specific policy goals, such as encouraging real economic substance. It is important to note that most elections, once made, are generally irrevocable for a specific period, some for one year and others for five years, and apply consistently to all Constituent Entities within a jurisdiction. This ensures stability and prevents MNEs from switching elections simply to minimize tax each year. Let's explore some of the key elections available: I. Elections related to GloBE income or loss calculation 1. Election to use the realization method for certain assets and liabilities (Fair Value Election) •Purpose: Under financial accounting, certain assets and liabilities, eg, financial instruments, investment properties, are often accounted for at fair value, with changes in value recognized in profit or loss even if not yet 'realized' through a sale. This can create volatility in GloBE Income. This election allows MNEs to use the realization principle instead, only recognizing gains or losses when the asset is actually sold or disposed of. •Relevance: Useful for MNEs with significant fair-valued assets, as it can smooth out fluctuations in their jurisdictional ETR, preventing sporadic top-up tax liabilities. 2. Stock-Based Compensation Election • Purpose: The accounting treatment for stock-based compensation, eg, employee share options, often differs significantly from its tax deductibility under domestic law. This election allows an MNE to substitute the amount of stock-based compensation deducted for domestic tax purposes for the amount expensed in the financial accounts when computing GloBE Income. • Relevance: Helps to align the GloBE Income more closely with the tax base that a jurisdiction considers for domestic tax purposes, reducing potential ETR distortions. 3. Election to Spread Capital Gains (or Losses) over Five Years: •Purpose: Significant gains or losses from the disposal of local tangible assets, like property or equipment, could dramatically skew an MNE's ETR in a single year. This election allows MNEs to spread such gains or losses over a five-year period for GloBE Income calculation. •Relevance: Provides a crucial mechanism to mitigate large, one-off ETR spikes or dips caused by asset sales, leading to a more stable and predictable GloBE tax outcome. 4 Equity investment inclusion election: •Purpose: Generally, gains or losses from changes in the fair value of equity investments are excluded from GloBE Income. However, some domestic tax systems might include such gains or losses in their taxable base. This election allows MNEs to include equity gains or losses, other than those related to certain passive or portfolio shareholdings, in GloBE Income to align with their domestic tax treatment. • Relevance: Addresses potential asymmetries where domestic tax is paid on these gains, but the income is not included in GloBE Income, preventing an artificially low ETR. 5 Portfolio Shareholding Election: •Purpose: Generally, dividends from portfolio shareholdings, i.e. minority interests, are excluded from GloBE Income. This election allows MNEs to include all dividends from portfolio shareholdings in their GloBE Income. o Relevance: Can simplify compliance if an MNE prefers to include all dividend income in its GloBE calculation. II. Elections related to adjusted covered taxes and loss treatment 1. GloBE Loss Election: •Purpose: The default GloBE rules rely on financial accounting deferred tax assets (DTAs) for losses. In jurisdictions with no corporate income tax, or very low tax, or where the DTA mechanism does not perfectly align with GloBE principles, this can lead to complexities. This election allows an MNE to create a deemed 'GloBE Loss Deferred Tax Asset' for net GloBE losses incurred in a jurisdiction, valued at the 15 percent minimum rate. This deemed DTA can then be used to reduce top-up tax in subsequent profitable years. •Relevance: Particularly useful for MNEs in jurisdictions that historically had very low or no corporate income tax, like Kuwait, for foreign entities before the QDMTT, or for domestic entities not subject to the QDMTT. It provides a more direct and often more beneficial way to account for past losses in jurisdictions that do not have a robust domestic deferred tax system. •Excess Negative Tax Carry-Forward Election: •Purpose: If the 'Adjusted Covered Taxes' for a jurisdiction become negative, e.g., due to a refundable tax credit that exceeds tax paid, this election allows MNEs to treat that negative amount as an 'Excess Negative Tax Expense Carryforward'. This can then be used to offset future positive Adjusted Covered Taxes, effectively smoothing out the ETR. •Relevance: Helps manage ETR volatility in years with significant tax refunds or credits. III. Elections for specific entity types and situations 1. Excluded entity election: •Purpose: While certain entities, like governmental entities, non-profits, or pension funds, are generally excluded from the GloBE Rules, an MNE can elect to not treat such an entity as excluded. •Relevance: This could be useful in very specific, rare circumstances where including the entity in the GloBE calculation might, paradoxically, reduce overall top-up tax due to favorable ETR outcomes. entity tax transparency election / taxable distribution method election: •Purpose: Investment entities, like some funds, often have unique tax treatments. These elections allow MNEs to align the GloBE treatment of investment entity income and taxes with how their owners are taxed under domestic law, e.g., treating the investment entity as transparent for GloBE purposes or taxing distributions when made. •Relevance: Crucial for accurate ETR calculation and avoiding top-up tax on investment income that is already effectively taxed at the owner level. 3. De minimis election (for jurisdictional exclusions): •Purpose: While not strictly an 'election' in the same sense as the others, the rules provide a 'de minimis exclusion' for jurisdictions where an MNE's operations are very small (average GloBE revenue under EUR 10 million and average GloBE income under EUR 1 million). This allows MNEs to elect to apply this exclusion, meaning no top-up tax is due for that jurisdiction. •Relevance: Significantly reduces the compliance burden for MNEs with minor presences in many countries, allowing them to focus resources on material jurisdictions. Kuwait's executive regulations include this. IV. Transitional elections and safe harbours 1. Transitional CbCR Safe harbour election: •Purpose: This is one of the most widely adopted and important elections for the initial years of Pillar Two, generally until June 30, 2028. It allows MNEs to avoid detailed GloBE calculations for a jurisdiction if they meet one of three tests based on their existing Country-by-Country Report (CbCR) data: De Minimis Test: If revenue and profit are below certain thresholds. Simplified ETR Test: If their simplified CbCR ETR is at or above a transitional rate, e.g., 15 percent for 2025, 16 percent for 2026, 17 percent for 2027. Routine Profits Test: If their profit before income tax is less than the substance-based income exclusion. • Relevance: Provides crucial temporary relief from the full complexity of GloBE calculations, allowing MNEs to phase in their compliance efforts. Kuwait's Law 157/2024 specifically provides for this. 2 QDMTT Safe harbour election: • Purpose: Where a country has a QDMTT, like Kuwait, this election can further simplify compliance. If an MNE's QDMTT calculation in Kuwait results in an ETR above 15 percent, or if the QDMTT is zero, they can elect to treat the top-up tax for GloBE purposes as zero for that jurisdiction, avoiding the need for further IIR and UTPR calculations for Kuwait. NOTE: Hassan M Abdulrahim is a Senior Instructor (Business) at Canadian College Kuwait and CEO & Co-founder of Visionary Consulting Company