
The statistical truth about American stagnation
A week ago I wrote a post arguing that globalization didn't hollow out the American middle class (as many people believe):
After I wrote the post, John Lettieri of the Economic Innovation Group wrote a great thread that strongly supports my argument. He showed that the timing of America's wage stagnation — roughly, 1973 through 1994 — just didn't line up well with the era of globalization that began with NAFTA in 1994. In fact, American wages started growing again right after NAFTA was passed. Source: John Lettieri
In fact, wage growth since NAFTA has been almost as strong as in the decades after World War 2!
Now, I think this might be too simple of a story. Although there was a lot of noise and political hand-wringing over NAFTA, most Americans probably don't think it was competition from Mexico that hollowed out the US middle class — they think it was China.
And while economists think NAFTA hurt some specific manufacturing industries in a few specific places, they generally conclude that it helped most Americans; it's the China Shock, after China's entry into the WTO in 2001, that many economists think was overall harmful to the working class.
And if you add the China Shock to Lettieri's timeline, you see that by some measures — but not by others — there's a second, shorter era of wage stagnation that lines up with it pretty well. I've modified Lettieri's charts to show the China Shock: Source: John Lettieri, modified by Noah Smith
You can see that median wages flatten out between 2003 and 2015, while average hourly earnings of production and nonsupervisory workers continue to rise.
Obviously, the Great Recession is the biggest factor after 2007 (and many economists believe the China Shock only lasted through 2007). But there's a good argument that Chinese competition did hold American wages down for a few years in the 2000s.
And in case you were wondering, here's the breakdown for men and women: Source: John Lettieri, modified by Noah Smith
And Lettieri has more charts showing that the story looks the same for the working class as it does for the middle class.
So I think the story is more nuanced than Lettieri makes it out to be. The surge in middle-class and working-class wages in the late 1990s might have come in spite of some small headwinds from NAFTA, and the China Shock might have exerted a drag on American wages during the 2000s.
But the much bigger story that these charts tell is that the biggest wage stagnation in modern American history came before the era of globalization — roughly from 1973 through 1994.
What was the cause of that epic stagnation? In macroeconomics, it's very hard to isolate cause and effect, since there are so many things going on at the same time. The decades between 1973 and 1994 featured two oil shocks, major inflation, two big changes in the global monetary regime, multiple major recessions, changes in trade deficits and imports, and plenty more.
So much was going on that it's possible that the wage stagnation was just a series of negative shocks that lasted for a long time — 'just one damn thing after another', as the saying goes.
But as a first pass, we can look at some of the theories of why that stagnation happened, and see if they match up with the timeline.
Part of the stagnation in wages was due to rising inequality. If we look at average versus median hourly compensation (which includes benefits like health insurance and retirement matching contributions), we see that the average stagnated less than the median: Sources: EPI, Fred
But you can still clearly see that from the early 1970s through the mid-1990s, the average value stagnated as well. This suggests that there was something systemic going on — it wasn't just the middle class getting hit.
Part of that 'something' was a productivity stagnation. If you look at average hourly compensation versus average labor productivity (output per hour worked), you see a modest divergence, but the productivity slowdown from the early 1970s until the mid 1990s is clearly visible, and it exactly lines up with the stagnation in wages :
Nobody knows exactly why productivity slowed down for two decades, but in my opinion, the leading candidate explanation is that the oil shock of 1973 inaugurated an era of energy scarcity that forced industrial economies to shift away from energy-intensive growth.
Is it also possible that the same underlying shifts that made productivity slow down during those two decades also caused inequality to rise, and labor's share of income to fall from 63% to 61% over the exact same period? It seems plausible, because the timing lines up so perfectly. But I don't know of a good theory as to how a technological shift could cause all of these things at once.
One common theory is that in the 1970s and 1980s, American industrial policy — including trade policy — stopped favoring manufacturing and started favoring the financial sector. This is, for example, the thesis of Judith Stein's 'Pivotal Decade: How the United States Traded Factories for Finance in the Seventies.' But if you look at the growth of the finance industry as a share of the US economy, it's a more or less unbroken rise from the end of WW2 through the turn of the century: Source: Greenwood & Scharfstein (2013)
And if you look at financial profits, these actually fell as a share of the total in the 1970s before surging in the 1980s and again in the late 90s and early 00s: Source: James Kwak
The timing here doesn't really line up. There's no clear measure of financialization that coincides specifically with the early 1970s through the mid-1990s. The explosion of finance profits in the 1980s might explain part of the wage stagnation, if it came via financiers putting pressure on companies to suppress wages.
But that can't explain the wage stagnation in the 1970s, nor the re-acceleration in the late 90s and early 00s (when financial profits exploded but wages did well).
A lot of research suggests that unions drive down economic inequality (though researchers disagree on exactly how big the effect is). Farber et al. (2021) write:
US income inequality has varied inversely with union density over the past hundred years…We develop a new source of microdata on union membership dating back to 1936, survey data primarily from Gallup (N ≈ 980,000), to examine the long-run relationship between unions and inequality…Using distributional decompositions, time-series regressions, state-year regressions, as well as a new instrumental-variable strategy based on the 1935 legalization of unions and the World-War- II era War Labor Board, we find consistent evidence that unions reduce inequality, explaining a significant share of the dramatic fall in inequality between the mid-1930s and late 1940s.
Here's a picture of that relationship: Source: Joe Nocera
As we saw above, wage inequality — the divergence between average and median compensation — was responsible for part of the stagnation in middle-class wages, though not all of it.
But the timing doesn't seem to fit here either. As you can see from that chart, unions have been in decline since the mid-1950s. The decline was a bit faster in the 1980s, which might slightly help explain wage stagnation in that decade. But overall, it's been pretty smooth. That doesn't match up with the 20-year wage stagnation that started in the early 70s and ended in the mid 90s.
The chart of real wages for production and nonsupervisory workers shows a dramatic slowdown from around 1973-1994. But a chart of nominal wages for those same workers — i.e. the actual number of dollars they earned per hour — shows no such slowdown, except maybe a very gentle flattening in the 1980s:
The difference, of course, is inflation. From around 1973 to 1983, prices increased at rapid rates:
The smoothness of nominal wage growth raises the possibility that nominal wage growth is very sticky — that workers are able to negotiate about the same number of additional dollars from year to year, despite big changes in the purchasing power of a dollar.
Again, the timing here doesn't line up with the era of wage stagnation. But I suppose it might explain the first half of it.
Finally, we're back to trade and globalization. Certainly, Americans worried a lot about competition from European and Japanese companies, especially in the early 1980s. The Japanese and European auto and machine tool industries really did put American companies under intense competitive pressure starting in the 1970s.
But it's very hard to see this effect in the aggregate statistics. Import penetration rose in the 1970s, but flatlined in the 1980s and early 1990s: Source: World Bank
As for the trade deficit, that was zero in the 1970s and then had a brief but temporary surge in the 1980s: Recall that the current account deficit is almost exactly the same as the trade deficit.
Some people I talk to seem to think that wage stagnation began as a result of the abolition of the Bretton Woods currency system in 1971-73. But that change, which ended the US dollar's role as the world's official reserve currency, caused the US dollar to depreciate, which made US exports more competitive and actually discouraged imports.
The dollar then surged again in the early 80s and collapsed in the late 80s after the Plaza Accord (an agreement to weaken the dollar): Source: Bloomberg
And the Japanese yen strengthened more or less steadily against the dollar during the entire period of wage stagnation.
So trade with Europe and Japan just doesn't line up with the wage stagnation in terms of timing, either. If you think overall import penetration is the key measure of globalization, then maybe trade had an effect in the 1970s; if you think trade deficits are a better measure, then maybe trade had an effect in the 1990s. But then the trade deficit and imports both surged in the late 1990s, which is when the wage stagnation ended.
In any case, we're left with a bit of a mystery. The only macro trend that lines up very neatly with the great wage stagnation of 1973-1994 is the productivity slowdown, but there's no good theory explaining how that could explain all of the wage stagnation, since productivity rose more than wages. Meanwhile, de-unionization, financialization, inflation, and trade with Europe and Japan can at best explain only some sub-periods of the wage stagnation — not the whole thing.
In fact, the great wage stagnation might have been from a patchwork of causes — first inflation and a surge of imports in the 70s, then accelerated de-unionization and financialization and the collapse of exports in the 1980s, with the productivity stagnation playing a corrosive role the whole time.
But we should always be suspicious of complex, multi-factorial explanations for trend breaks on a chart. That wage stagnation started and ended suddenly enough that it cries out for a simple story. We just don't have one yet.
Update: Some people have been asking me if the wage stagnation of 1973-1994 might have been caused by the mass entry of women into the US workforce. Here's the employment rate (also called the 'employment-population ratio') for American women:
You can see that the first part of the timing doesn't line up here. When the wage stagnation began, American women had already been entering the workforce at a steady clip for 25 years. (The labor force participation rate for women looks much the same).
Also, empirical evidence suggests at most a small effect of female labor supply on male wages — and if you look at the breakdown for men and women, you see that the stagnation for men was worse than for women over 1973-1994.
And theoretically speaking, women's mass entry into the workforce shouldn't produce an overall decline in wages. Just like immigration or a baby boom, women's entry into the workforce is both a positive labor supply shock and also a positive labor demand shock at the same time — when women earn more, they spend most of what they earn, on things that require labor to produce.1 So we shouldn't expect the addition of women to the workforce to hold down wages.
Thus, this theory also doesn't line up with the timing of the stagnation, and it's not clear why we would expect it to be a major factor in the first place.
This article was first published on Noah Smith's Noahpinion Substack and is republished with kind permission. Become a Noahopinion subscriber here.
Hashtags

Try Our AI Features
Explore what Daily8 AI can do for you:
Comments
No comments yet...
Related Articles


Asia Times
a day ago
- Asia Times
Hopes for a Xi-Trump summit are naively misplaced
US President Donald Trump and Chinese President Xi Jinping's surprise phone call—marking the first direct communication between the leaders in months—may signal a temporary thaw in an otherwise frosty and structurally adversarial relationship. While America's restoration of Chinese student visas and China's resumption of blocked critical mineral trade suggest detente, this contact, like others in the history of US-China summits, could quickly prove to be more performative than substantive. The danger lies not in dialogue but in the illusion that the leader-to-leader call, which Beijing insisted Trump requested, will meaningfully alter the deep geopolitical, ideological and economic divergences that define Sino-American relations today. News reports said Xi told Trump to roll back tariffs and other trade measures that are roiling the global economy while warning him about intensifying the dispute over Taiwan. Trump claimed on social media that the call delivered a 'positive conclusion', including on China's restrictions on critical mineral exports, and that lower-level discussions on trade would follow. He said, 'We're in very good shape with China and the trade deal.' Both leaders invited each other to visit their countries. However, reports noted that there was nothing in either side's official statements to indicate the critical mineral issue had been resolved. And China has reasonable cause to remain on guard despite Trump's post-call positivity. Let us count the many impediments to real and lasting reconciliation: The most acute danger stems from Trump's lack of strategic coherence. Unlike the Kissinger-Nixon doctrine of detente, which was structured, calculated and guided by a realpolitik vision of global balance, Trump's approach is reactive and transactional and thus prone to Chinese manipulation. Concessions, including the reopening of student exchanges on the US side and lifting critcal mineral restrictions on China's—appear to be issued in exchange for vague 'reciprocity' rather than any long-term strategic realignment. For Beijing, such inconsistency is easily exploitable. Xi understands that Trump is prone to tactical surprises and policy reversals, allowing China to notch one-by-one concessions while offering minimal structural reforms or broad policy changes in return. This understanding of Trump's tactics and views may also embolden China to keep testing US resolve and commitment in the Taiwan Strait, East Sea and South China Seas, knowing that by doing so it strengthens its negotiating leverage in wresting future US concessions. Much has been made of US-endorsed 'de-risking' from China without actually 'decoupling.' The resumption of trade in critical minerals—crucial to US defense and clean energy sectors—signals a potential pause in America's techno-economic containment of China, which if lasting, would contradict the bipartisan consensus in Washington that China poses a 'systemic challenge.' This could also send mixed messages to allies such as Japan, South Korea and key ASEAN economies, many of which are now being pressured to restrict technology transfers to China, particularly in regard to AI and quantum computing. If Trump reverses this posture, potentially at a Trump-Xi in-person summit, it would necessarily undercut the anti-China coalition the US has been trying to build since 2017 and signal a climbdown of epic proportions. An in-person summit with Xi would give both leaders global optics, something they arguably both need as their hardline stances cause political tremors at home and restlessness abroad. Yet symbolism without substance carries its own risks. The 2019 Mar-a-Lago summit and the 2018 G20 truce in Argentina were celebrated photo ops that ultimately yielded few strategic gains. Indeed, they were followed by tariff escalations, cyber accusations and deepened distrust. Xi, ever conscious of China's 'national rejuvenation' drive, may use a summit with Trump to signal that China is not isolated—even amid Western efforts to contain it – and that he brought the US to heel through his tough negotiating posture. Should he succeed in presenting Trump as a president willing to do business without political preconditions, it will bolster China's power on the world stage. This symbolism would serve Xi well amid research that shows China is straining under the weight of assisting various countries when its own economy remains fragile. There will be a temptation to portray a Trump-Xi summit as a return to the two sides' previous 'managed rivalry' model. Yet this notion is predicated on mutual trust, which no longer exists. A brief thaw may offer breathing space for both, but there is no sign yet of lasting strategic stability. During the previous Cold War, the US and Soviet Union were able to negotiate arms control and crisis management protocols. No such guardrails exist between the US and China today. The resumption of critical mineral trade and educational exchanges, while welcome, won't be enough to reverse mutual mistrust, especially when military encounters in the Taiwan Strait or the South China Sea could easily still spiral out of control. Increasingly politicized charges against Chinese nationals in the US are fueling that mistrust. Those include new accusations that China is involved in 'agro-terrorism' that aims to wipe out US barley, wheat and corn yields by up to 50%. A PhD researcher of Chinese origin at the University of Michigan has been arrested in this connection. A potential Trump-Xi summit – despite stage-managed positive vibes and smiles for the cameras, could be yet another empty ritual—a theatrical handshake over unresolved and deep contradictions. To be sure, both leaders have reasons to engage. Trump seeks headlines as his popularity slips ahead of 2026 midterm elections; Xi seeks legitimacy for his tough negotiating posture that risks millions of Chinese factory jobs. But neither is offering a strategic roadmap that can reassure domestic or global audiences. Without a shared understanding of what strategic competition entails, and without mechanisms for escalation control, the optics of detente will only mask a rivalry that still threatens to spiral deeper and deeper into conflict.


Asia Times
a day ago
- Asia Times
Ukraine's attacks on Russia risk major retaliation
Subscribe now with a one-month trial for only $1, then enjoy the first year at an exclusive rate of just $99. Kiev's high-risk strikes bring war to new precipice James Davis analyzes the sharp escalation in the Ukraine war marked by Ukrainian drone strikes on Russian strategic air bases and infrastructure, moves that have put mounting hardline pressure on Vladimir Putin to abandon peace talks and shift toward 'total war.' Poland's vote heralds a Trump-aligned turn in Central Europe Diego Faßnacht analyzes the election of nationalist candidate Karol Nawrocki as Poland's new president. He argues his victory could foreshadow a rightward realignment in Central Europe that is skeptical of Brussels and increasingly in sync with US Republicans. Trump doubles down on failing China sanctions Scott Foster argues that escalating US export controls on advanced technology are backfiring, accelerating China's tech self-sufficiency and innovation, as well as its scale-building efforts in AI, semiconductors, and aerospace, eroding American market dominance.


RTHK
2 days ago
- RTHK
China to protect firms as US toughens listing rules
China to protect firms as US toughens listing rules Spokesman Lin Jian says the US should not politicise economic and trade issues. Photo: Foreign Ministry website The Foreign Ministry said China would take whatever measures are necessary to protect the legitimate rights and interests of the country's companies. "The United States should abide by the market regulation of fair competition and stop politicising economic and trade issues," ministry spokesman Lin Jian said. The ministry was responding to Wall Street's top regulator taking a step towards toughening rules for foreign companies listed on American stock markets. The US Securities and Exchange Commission said many Chinese firms in particular benefited from having to make fewer regular disclosures to investors. It voted unanimously to call for public comment on possible new regulations that would narrow the definition of those foreign companies, known as foreign private issuers, that are required to publish only annual reports and occasional updates. US firms trading on the same stock exchanges fall under the full scope of American securities laws, including quarterly financial reporting, proxy solicitation rules and prompt disclosure of events such as mergers and the departures of board members. Any new regulations for foreign companies could make it more costly and challenging for many to tap US equity markets. (Reuters)