
MAGA's overreaching anti-economists get it all wrong
Oren Cass, the founder of the think tank American Compass, is probably the leading intellectual voice of MAGA economics. In a recent blog post, he discusses the question of whether economic forces are like gravity. He writes:
[Y]es, the physical world is governed by the laws of gravity. But it is not governed only by the laws of gravity. Indeed, anyone who thought he could reliably predict the motion of bodies with knowledge only of gravity would be something of a moron.
Oh, really? Would such a man be a moron? Then please explain to me how Edmond Halley, using only his knowledge of gravity, and having no understanding of any of the other forces of nature, was able to predict a solar eclipse in 1715 to an accuracy of four minutes:
In 1715…a total solar eclipse was visible across a broad band of England. It was the first to be predicted on the basis of the Newtonian theory of universal gravitation, its path mapped clearly and advertised widely in advance. Visible in locations such as London and Cambridge, both astronomical experts and the public were able to see the phenomena and be impressed by the predictive power of the new astronomy…
Wikipedia will tell you that this is known as Halley's Eclipse, after Edmond Halley, who produced accurate predictions of its timing and an easily-read map of the eclipse's path. Halley did not live to see the confirmation of his predictions of a returning comet – a 1759 triumph for the Newtonian system – but he was able to enjoy his 1715 calculations, which were within 4 minutes[.]
Cass — who holds a Bachelor's in political economy from Williams College and a law degree from Harvard, but has no apparent training in physics — confidently assures us that anyone who attempted what Edmond Halley did would be 'something of a moron.'
This is the kind of insult that says less about the target than about the person doing the insulting. Before you make confident assertions about a field of study, you owe it to your readers to attempt to understand that field at least a little bit.
A botched physics analogy is harmless enough. But Cass' main argument isn't about gravity at all — it's about economics. And it's here where his willingness to make grand pronouncements about whole fields of study gets him into real trouble.
Cass' post is a response to a Wall Street Journal op-ed by Matthew Hennessey. Hennessey, in turn, is responding to J.D. Vance's declaration that markets are a 'tool.' Hennessey argues that markets are more like a force of nature than a tool.1 Cass is trying to rebut Hennessey, criticizing market fundamentalism while also taking a swipe at the entire discipline of economics.
Now, I am no fan of market fundamentalism, and I spent my early years as a blogger bashing the field of (macro)economics — often with even more scorn than Oren Cass employs in this post. But I like to think that when I did this, I generally stuck to making specific criticisms about actual economic models and methods.
A lot of econ critics don't do this. Back when I was at Bloomberg, I used to have fun poking at the grandiose broadsides against economics that periodically appear in British publications like The Guardian or The Telegraph.
These critiques tend to repeat the same old nostrums over and over — economics isn't a science, it doesn't do controlled experiments, its assumptions are bad, its theories don't work, people can't be predicted like particles, etc. etc.
There are grains of truth to these boilerplate critiques, but the people who write them generally haven't bothered to pay much attention to what modern economists actually do . Here's what I wrote in a Bloomberg post back in 2017:
[E]conomists have developed some theories that really work. A good scientific theory makes testable predictions that apply to situations other than those that motivated the creation of the theory. Slowly, econ is building up a repertoire of these gems. One of them is auction theory, which predicts how buyers will bid for things like online ads or spectrum rights — Google's profits are powered by econ theory as much as by search algorithms. Another example is matching theory, which has made it a lot easier to get an organ transplant. A third is random-utility discrete choice theory, which is used in everything from marketing to transportation planning to disaster preparedness.
Nor are econ's successful theories limited to microeconomics. Gravity models of trade, though fairly simple in nature, have proven very successful at predicting the flow of international trade.
These and other successful economics theories can be used confidently in a wide-variety of real-world situations, by policy makers, engineers and businesses. They prove that anyone who claims that econ theories will never be reliable, because they deal with human beings instead of atoms, is simply incorrect.
Yes, studying mass human behavior is different than studying the motions of the planets, in a number of important ways. But the intellectuals who loftily declare that economics 'isn't a science' don't seem like they've bothered to think very hard about what those differences are , or when and why they matter.
For example, what do the people who write that 'economics isn't a science' think about natural experiments — the empirical technique that has taken over much of econ research in the last three decades? Do they think that these are always less informative than lab experiments in the natural sciences?
And if so, why? What do they think are the strengths and weaknesses of natural experiments relative to lab experiments, and how much can they help us test theories and derive general principles about how economies work?
I suspect that very few of the econ critics have thought seriously about these questions, and that far too few have even heard of natural experiments. Certainly, if they have, they must have some good reason for never mentioning them.
And certainly they must have good reasons for never talking about auction theory, matching theory, discrete choice models, gravity models, or any of the other economics theories that prove themselves in the real world day in and day out. Right?
But the screeds in The Guardian or The Telegraph are downright erudite compared to what Oren Cass serves up in his own criticism of econ. Here's what he writes:
Economics is nothing like physics. Its principles are not generated from repeatable experiments, nor do they hold consistently across space and time. Trusting otherwise is a quite literal example of the blind faith and fundamentalism at issue.
That's it. That's literally Cass' entire criticism of the field of economics in this post. He spends the rest of the post pulling quotes from conservative political thinkers — G.K. Chesterton, Robert Nisbet, Yuval Levin, Roger Scruton, etc. — who urge us to value things like community, tradition, etc., or who assert that markets can't work without a robust social fabric. Those are interesting things to think about, to be sure, but they don't bear on the question of what, exactly, Cass thinks is so inadequate about economics.
Cass does not name or criticize any specific economic theories in this post. He cites zero papers and names zero researchers. I looked through a bunch of his other posts about economics, and I almost never found him naming or criticizing any specific theories in those posts, either.
In one post, I did find him criticizing the theory of comparative advantage, and he did make one useful, substantive point about it — that comparative advantage can't explain trade deficits and surpluses. He's right about that. That's by far the most substantive, knowledgeable criticism of economics that I could find on his blog.
If Cass is aware of any economic models other than comparative advantage and the basic Econ 101 supply-and-demand model, he plays his cards close to his chest. He doesn't mention gravity models of trade, which some economists use to try to predict the effects of tariffs (with some success).
Nor does he mention Paul Krugman's New Trade Theory, which implies that countries can sometimes benefit from targeted tariffs against other countries' national champions (but which wouldn't recommend the kind of broad, sweeping tariffs Trump has tried to implement).
Neither of those theories is outside the mainstream; both were invented by economists who went on to win the Nobel. Why doesn't Oren Cass mention them, or grapple with their implications, or use their existence to inform his criticisms of the field of economics?
My guess — and this is only a guess — is that Cass is completely unaware that these theories exist, that he has no interest in discovering whether such theories exist, that if he did discover them he would have no idea how to evaluate them, and that even if he did know how to evaluate them he would have no interest in doing so.
A sophisticated understanding of what mainstream economics actually says and does is not useful to Oren Cass' project, which is to denounce intellectual rivals within the conservative movement.
If you want to actually figure out how trade works and what tariffs do, it would help to look at the research literature. If you didn't get the training needed to understand that literature, it would help to ask some people who did get that training, or at least read a little Wikipedia and ask ChatGPT a few questions.2
That won't give you all the answers — the world's best economists don't even have all the answers — but it would leave you a lot more knowledgeable than you started out, and it would give you a much better idea of where economists are on solid ground and where there are gaps in their understanding.
On the other hand, if all you want is to dunk on Wall Street Journal writers, perhaps all you need is some hand-waving rhetoric about 'market fundamentalism' and a vague half-knowledge of one simple trade theory developed 200 years ago.
The real problem with these econ critics — both the lefty writers in The Guardian and the new crop of MAGA defenders — is that their project is fundamentally political. The lefty writers think that if everyone accepts that econ isn't a science, and that the econ Nobel isn't a real Nobel, and people aren't like particles, and so on and so forth, then some sort of lefty ideology — Marxism, or degrowth, or whatever — will flow in to fill the hole left when economics vanishes. The MAGA writers think that it will be Trump's economic ideas that fill that void instead.
But Matthew Hennessey, the Wall Street Journal writer, got one big thing right: Simply replacing academic theories with your own ideology can win you power, but there are important things it can't do. It can't change the nature of what tariffs actually do to the economy.
Even if you and your friends and your political allies all shout very loudly that tariffs will restore American manufacturing, and act very scornful toward nerdy academics who tell you it doesn't work like that, the economic headwinds that tariffs actually create for American manufacturers won't change one iota.
However limited mainstream academic economics is as a tool for understanding the consequences of your policies, ideology is even worse.
NOTES:
1 Who's right, Vance or Hennesey? Both are right. Market forces are , quite literally, forces of nature. And markets themselves are, quite literally, a tool. Tools work by harnessing forces of nature. A pendulum clock works by harnessing the force of gravity. A market works by harnessing the forces that drive people to buy and sell things. Vance is right that markets should be shaped to serve our desired ends, rather than being an end in and of themselves. Hennesey is right that market forces can't be denied, ignored, or wished away.
2 Just to see how AI is doing, I asked ChatGPT o3 about the papers on gravity models. Its characterization of the papers' results was oversimplified and omitted crucial nuance about the ex ante predictive accuracy of Fejgelbaum et al. (2020). But overall, its explanations weren't too bad!
This article was first published on Noah Smith's Noahpinion Substack and is republished with kind permission. Become a Noahopinion subscriber here.

Try Our AI Features
Explore what Daily8 AI can do for you:
Comments
No comments yet...
Related Articles


Asia Times
2 hours ago
- Asia Times
Did Trump know about Ukraine's drone blitz in advance?
Ukraine's strategic drone strikes on Sunday against elements of Russia's nuclear triad all across the country were an unprecedented provocation that risks a dramatic worsening of the conflict. Speculation has since swirled about whether Trump knew about these attacks in advance, which his Press Secretary denied. What follows are five relevant points, each accompanied by brief arguments about why they either do or do not prove that he really was aware, which will help readers make up their own mind: 1. Trump is Pushing For A Record Trillion-Dollar Defense Budget * Escalating and then maintaining tensions with Russia, but importantly keeping them manageable, would create a sense of urgency in Congress for passing this record budget by year's end and reduce opposition to it from key MAGA allies. The military-industrial complex is influential in Trump 2.0 and he himself has always boasted about how powerful he wants the US Armed Forces to become. He might thus have known about Ukraine's drone strike plans in advance, but didn't call them off for this reason. – Trump has invested a lot of political capital in trying to de-escalate tensions with Russia and caught tons of flak as a result, yet he still officially remains committed to it (at least for now), thus suggesting sincerity. Regarding his proposed defense budget, it may be more about preparing the US for war with China, rather than waging another endless war against Russia by proxy. There's also wide congressional approval for containing China, so his defense budget likely doesn't need escalated tensions with Russia to pass. 2. Trump Surprisingly Patched Up His Problems With Zelensky * The minerals deal, Trump's latest in-person meeting with Zelensky at the Vatican, and the influence of the US' permanent military, intelligence, and diplomatic bureaucracies ('deep state') might have combined to reshape Trump's perception of both Zelensky and Putin. It might therefore be that while Trump talks about peace with Putin in public, he's plotting against him during talks with Zelensky. Their latest in-person meeting could have even seen Trump approve of Zelensky's strategic drone strike plans. – Trump is profit-minded and mercurial so it makes sense that his attitude towards Zelensky changed for the better after the minerals deal was finally signed. Likewise, his inability to reach any similar or more significant deals with Putin – which are dependent on first freezing or resolving the Ukrainian conflict – accounts for his newly harsh rhetoric about him. Had Trump known about Zelensky's plans in advance, then he'd have called them off so as to not risk losing these potential deals with Putin in the aftermath. 3. Trump Warned That 'REALLY BAD' Things Might Soon Happen To Russia * His scandalous post came less than a week before Ukraine's strategic drone strikes and might have thus meant to foreshadow this unprecedented provocation, albeit in a 'plausibly deniable' way for escalation-control purposes. Trump could have also wanted to signal to Putin that he'd better accept an unconditional 30-day ceasefire or else. If that's really what happened, then he might be preparing another such post for the same reason, which he'd hope might then pressure Putin into concessions. – Critics claim that Trump sometimes bluffs as a negotiating tactic so this might have been one example of that in practice on the world's stage. The wording and timing coincidentally served the relevant interests of the Biden-era 'deep state,' which could have cooked up this unprecedented provocation long ago without him ever finding out, given that it might implicate Trump in Putin's eyes. In that event, the peace process might collapse, and Trump might thus escalate in response just like they want. 4. Axios Initially Claimed That Ukraine Informed The US In Advance * Although Axios later corrected its report to note that Ukraine did not inform the US in advance, its initial claim might have been accurate, but understandable escalation-control concerns vis-à-vis Russia could have prompted the White House to urgently request that they change it. Axios might have voluntarily complied for national security reasons or because it was coerced with legal threats. In any case, this incident convinced some people that Trump really was aware of Ukraine's plans in advance. – Axios either made an innocent error in its initial report that was then swiftly corrected, or this was a preplanned provocation by Democrat-loyal elements of the 'deep state' to falsely implicate Trump. If the second scenario is what happened, then the purpose would have been to convince Putin that Trump really was aware of Ukraine's plans in advance, which could then trigger the peace process's collapse. Even so, Russia is well aware of the 'deep state's' tricks, so it might not fall for this latest possible one. 5. Trump Has Remained Suspiciously Silent About These Attacks * For someone who seems to always have an opinion about everything, even the most mundane and random things, Trump hasn't yet said a word about Ukraine's unprecedented provocation against Russia. His suspicious silence is thus being interpreted by some as tacit approval. After all, these strategic drone strikes risk triggering the collapse of the peace process into which he's already invested so much political capital, so it follows that he'd have condemned Ukraine by now if he was really against what it did. – Trump might have been caught off guard by this just as much as Putin was if the Biden-era 'deep state' really did cook this up long ago without him ever finding out. Therefore, both of them might have agreed – whether during an unreported phone call on Sunday or during their top diplomats' one that same day – to play it cool while jointly investigating, thus keeping the peace process alive for now. In that case, Trump's silence would be temporary, and Putin would already know not to misconstrue it as acceptance. ———- Whether Trump knew about Ukraine's strategic strikes in advance will determine the extent of Russia's retaliation and whether it remains involved in the peace process. The best-case scenario from Russia's perspective is that Putin becomes convinced that Trump didn't know and that he then acts against those in his government that did, while the worst-case scenario is Putin concluding that Trump knew and either approved it, didn't care or couldn't stop it but didn't inform him. This article was first published on Andrew Korybko's Substack and is republished with kind permission. Become an Andrew Korybko Newsletter subscriber here.


South China Morning Post
15 hours ago
- South China Morning Post
Sorry, but the ‘China shock' was actually pretty good for America
The idea that China has stolen millions of American jobs in recent decades, causing a collapse in the manufacturing labour market, has long been a staple anti-Chinese narrative on both sides of US politics. Even economists and media pundits who grudgingly acknowledge that cheap Chinese goods have made life easier and more affordable for the average American would complain about these alleged mass job losses. And the blue-collar voters most severely affected by sectoral lay-offs and the decline in regional manufacturing make up a fair segment of Donald Trump 's Maga – 'Make America Great Again' – movement. But is this so-called China shock actually real? 09:42 Trump promises to bring US manufacturing back from China, but will his tariffs work? Trump promises to bring US manufacturing back from China, but will his tariffs work? Among the most influential research defending the 'China shock' claim is a series of papers by David Autor of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, David Dorn of the University of Zurich, and Gordon Hanson of the Harvard Kennedy School – especially their 2016 paper 'The China Shock: Learning from Labour Market Adjustment to Large Changes in Trade'.


Asia Times
a day ago
- Asia Times
Karl Marx is back—and he thinks you Americans are clowns
Karl Marx is having a moment—again. Not a polite classroom cameo. Not a dusty citation buried in a syllabus. No, we're talking prime-time revival, with publishers, podcasters and politicos all vying to resurrect the bearded prophet of class war. Princeton just dropped a new translation of ' Capital ' —the first in 50 years. Bernie Sanders remains the most famous living socialist on Earth. TikTok teens quote 'seize the means' between lip-syncs and thirst traps. And MAGA diehards bark 'Marxist!' at everything from school libraries to seatbelt laws. Welcome to the fourth Marx boom, as historian Andrew Hartman calls it. But let's get one thing clear: most people talking about Marx—left, right or libertarian—have no idea what they're actually invoking. Because Marx, the man, the theorist, the firestarter, has become less a thinker and more a Rorschach test. A ghost conjured by the Left for moral clarity and by the Right for moral panic. And yet, buried beneath the hysteria, is something worth looking at. Not because Marx offers the answers but because he was asking the right questions. And America—bloated, twitchy, unequal—is finally in a position to understand them. Marx wasn't about equality. He was about power. This is the first mistake people make. They think Marx was some utopian, frothing about 'fairness' or 'equity' like a modern DEI consultant. He wasn't. Marx was a power analyst. His lens wasn't moral—it was mechanical. You either owned the means of production, or you didn't. Everything else—religion, culture, law—was scaffolding. Set dressing. A way to keep the underclass sedated. Marx never said capitalism made people mean. He said it made them replaceable . A system that turns humans into units of labor, not out of malice, but efficiency. And if you don't see that reality in Uber drivers, Amazon warehouses or AI ghostwriters cannibalizing creative work, you're blind. Why Marx appeals to America's lost generation Marx is back in fashion because America, in many ways, is more Marxist in condition than it has ever been. Not ideologically but structurally. A bloated elite hoards wealth and real estate. The middle class is evaporating faster than coastal cities. Work offers no security, only subscriptions. And even the fantasy of upward mobility has been repossessed. Enter a generation saddled with debt, raised on screens, priced out of housing and force-fed bootstraps ideology while watching billionaires LARP as demigods. These young Americans don't want communism, but they're furious at capitalism. Marx didn't give them hope. He gave them blame . And blame is power's most dangerous counterforce. The irony of the American Marxist boom The deeper irony? Marx wouldn't have recognized most of today's 'Marxists.' Cultural obsessives more focused on pronouns than property. Tenured radicals clinging to academia like landlords to rent checks. Corporate HR departments using DEI training as a smokescreen for crushing union talk. Marx believed in material struggle, not identity kabuki. To him, class wasn't just one axis among many—it was the engine room. Everything else, including race and gender, flowed from the economic base. The modern Left has flipped that model inside out, often without realizing it. That's not Marxism. That's mood-board activism. The 2025 translation of ' Capital ' by Princeton is being billed as 'Marx for the twenty-first century.' But that phrase is more revealing than it intends. Because it's not about updating Marx—it's about updating us . It's about whether we're finally ready to read him not as a revolutionary or relic, but as a systems analyst. A brutal, unsentimental one. He didn't want your virtue. He wanted your audit. He wanted to know who owned the factory, and why. Who owned the newspaper? Who funded the revolution? And who pretended they didn't? What the Right Gets wrong Conservatives love to shout 'Marxist!' like it's a spell that makes your enemies disappear. But what they often miss is that capitalism itself has become post-capitalist in structure. The free market is a museum piece. What we have now is something closer to algorithmic feudalism, where tech oligarchs own the infrastructure of communication, culture and commerce. Not factories—servers. Not railroads—data. Marx saw feudalism mutate into capitalism. What he didn't live long enough to see was capitalism mutate into platform monopolies. If the lords once controlled land, and the industrialists controlled labor, today's titans control the interface. And when you control the interface, you don't need to own the worker. You just own their access to work. What the Left gets wrong The Left romanticizes Marx but forgets he was diagnosing disease, not prescribing utopia. He didn't tell you what to build—he just showed you what would collapse. Every time someone waves a hammer-and-sickle flag while sipping Starbucks and tweeting about revolution, a ghost in Highgate Cemetery rolls its eyes. The real tragedy is that the Left, by abandoning class for cultural abstraction, has forfeited the very tools Marx gave them. They're trying to cut steel with slogans. They've replaced critique with vibes. And the ruling class couldn't be more thrilled. Marx doesn't need to be right, just useful. Of course, Marx got many things wrong. He underestimated capitalism's plasticity. He misunderstood the role of the middle class. And he didn't see how consumerism would morph exploitation into entertainment. But he understood cycles. He saw how inequality, left unchecked, hollows out empires. He saw how narratives are used to justify hierarchies. And he saw that the people most confident in their system are usually the ones who benefit most from not questioning it. Sound familiar? You don't have to be a Marxist to read Marx. You just have to be awake. Because for all the noise, what's unfolding in America isn't a cultural revolution—it's a class reckoning. And if you look past the hashtags and hysteria, you'll see that Marx isn't returning as a prophet. He's returning as a mirror. And America, bloated and broken and blindfolded by its own exceptionalism, is finally starting to look.